Working paper

Trade and Migration to New Zealand (WP 04/18)

Formats and related files

Authors: John Bryant, Murat Genç and David Law

Abstract#

This paper examines the hypothesis that a greater stock of migrants in New Zealand from a particular country leads to more trade between that country and New Zealand. The literature suggests that migrants can stimulate trade by lowering transaction costs, and by bringing with them preferences for goods produced in their home country. We use panel data techniques within the framework of a standard gravity model of trade. Our sample includes an average of over 170 countries for the years 1981 to 2001. Previous studies of trade and migration have not dealt satisfactorily with problems of unobserved heterogeneity and selection bias. We address these problems using correlated random effects and selection models. Results suggest that larger migrant stocks are associated with higher trade flows.

Acknowledgements#

Thank you to William Greene, Dean Hyslop, Jacques Poot, Jim Rose, Richard Downing, Philip Liu, members of Treasury’s Applied Econometrics Group, and our colleagues in the Policy Coordination and Development Section for their contributions to this paper. This paper has also benefited from comments received in seminars given at Canterbury and Otago Universities, The New Zealand Association of Economists conference, The New Zealand Econometrics Study Group and the Australasian Meeting of the Econometric Society.

Disclaimer#

The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this Working Paper are strictly those of the authors. They do not necessarily reflect the views of the New Zealand Treasury. The New Zealand Treasury takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the information contained in this Working Paper. The paper is presented not as policy, but to inform and stimulate wider debate.

1  Introduction#

Migrants have language skills, local knowledge, and access to international networks that can help overcome barriers to trade. Increasing the number of migrants from a country might therefore be expected to stimulate trade with that country. Econometric analyses in the United States, Canada, Britain, and Spain find support for this hypothesis. One study even found a link between migration and trade for internal migration between different regions of France (Combes, Lafourcade and Mayer 2003). Such effects are potentially important in explaining New Zealand’s recent trade performance, as the country’s migrant population has become significantly larger and more diverse over the past 20 years.

This paper presents an econometric analysis of the effects of migration on trade in New Zealand. It tests the hypothesis that, all else equal, a larger stock of migrants from a given country increases New Zealand’s imports from and exports to that country. As with previous studies of migration and trade, the starting point is a gravity model of trade, in which trade is a function of the size of two economies and the distance between them. As well as looking at the overall relationship between migration and trade, the paper also examines whether the relationship between migration and trade differs with the nature of the goods traded, the migrants’ origin countries, and the number of migrants. Previous studies have been restricted to merchandise trade. We also look briefly at the effect of migration on international tourism (which in 2001 earned New Zealand an estimated $NZ5.1 billion).[1] The analysis draws on an unusually rich dataset—panel data on more than 170 countries over 21 years—which enhances our ability to deal with the econometric problems of unobserved heterogeneity and selection bias.

Section 2 of the paper gives a brief overview of recent trends in migration and trade in New Zealand. Section 3 summarises ideas from the international literature on why migration might stimulate trade. Section 4 provides some evidence on the activities of migrants in New Zealand. Section 5 summarises the results from previous econometric analyses. Section 6 describes our methodology, and Section 7 our results. The final section summarises our findings and discusses their implications.

Notes

  • [1]This figure excludes international airfares and applies to the year to June.  It was obtained from the International Visitors Survey, on the Tourism New Zealand website www.tourisminfo.govt.nz.

Between 1981 and 2001 the number of people usually resident in New Zealand who stated on their census forms that they were born overseas rose from 450,000 to 698,000, an increase of 55%. As Table 1 shows, the sources of migrants also became more diverse, with particularly large increases in the number of migrants from East Asia and the Pacific. The data in Table 1 suggest that New Zealand is starting to develop migrant communities from an increasingly wide variety of countries. Detailed examination bears this out. For instance, the number of countries for which New Zealand had at least one thousand migrants increased from 28 in 1981 to 48 in 2001, and the number of countries for which New Zealand had at least 10 thousand migrants increased from 5 to 16.[2]

Most analysts trace the dramatic changes in New Zealand’s migrant population to changes in immigration policy. From the mid-1980s official preferences for “traditional” migrant sources were ended, and decisions were based mostly on personal characteristics such as qualifications and age (Lidgard, Bedford and Goodwin 1998). In the case of some East Asian countries, rapid income growth in the migrants’ home countries also presumably played a role. This provides partial reassurance that migration was not responding to trade per se, which would bias upwards our estimates of the effect of migration on trade.[3]

Table 1 – Changes in New Zealand’s migrant stock, exports, and imports, by region, 1981-2001
  Population by region of birth (thousands) Exports by region (NZ$1995 millions) Imports by region  (NZ$1995 millions)
  1981 2001 Incr. 1981 2001 Incr. 1981 2001 Incr.
Australia 44 56 28% 1,343 4,844 261% 1,529 5,741 275%
East Asia & Pacific 76 253 233% 2,688 9,066 237% 2,611 7,859 201%
Europe & Central Asia 47 67 42% 1,317 2,612 98% 898 4,236 372%
Mid East & N Africa 2 12 679% 692 800 16% 661 1,380 109%
North America 12 21 81% 1,337 4,300 222% 1,721 4,615 168%
South America 2 4 74% 212 1,192 462% 60 327 445%
South Asia 7 31 313% 126 323 156% 62 244 294%
Sub-Saharan Africa 8 36 381% 57 160 181% 28 123 339%
United Kingdom 253 217 -14% 1,166 1,221 5% 770 1,006 31%
Unspecified 14 149 979% 476 1,087 128% 123 681 454%
New Zealand 2,679 2,891 8% - - - - - -
Total 3,143 3,737 19% 9,413 25,605 172% 8,463 26,212 210%

Source – Population data from Statistics New Zealand unpublished census tabulations. Trade estimates calculated from the United Nations Statistics Division’s Comtrade database. The original Comtrade data were denominated in US dollars. See the text for a description of the conversion to NZ dollars.

New Zealand’s imports and exports have also grown substantially over the period 1981-2001. Table 1 presents estimates based on data from the United Nations Commodity Trade Database (Comtrade). Trade values in Comtrade are reported in nominal US dollars; we have converted these into 1995 NZ dollars by multiplying by the NZ-US exchange rate, and then dividing by Statistics New Zealand’s aggregate merchandise import and export price deflators.[4]

As with migration, there is substantial geographic variation in growth rates. Trade with the United Kingdom, for instance, has increased relatively little, while trade with South America has increased markedly. New Zealand has increased the number of countries with which it conducts substantial international trade. Between 1981 and 2001, the number of countries from which New Zealand imported goods worth at least $100 million (in 1995 NZ dollars) increased from 13 to 31. During the same period, the number of countries to which New Zealand exported goods worth at least $100 million increased from 20 to 29.

Notes

  • [2]Bryant and Law (2004) contains a more detailed analysis of trends in New Zealand’s foreign-born population.
  • [3]For more discussion on the direction of causation between migration and trade see Gould (1994: 310).
  • [4]We calculated annual exchange rates by averaging the International Monetary Fund’s monthly rates.  It would have been preferable to have used country-specific import and export price deflators.  However, country-specific deflators are available only for New Zealand’s top five trading partners.

3  Mechanisms through which migration could stimulate trade#

Following Gould (1994), most authors postulate two mechanisms through which migration could stimulate trade between the host and origin countries: “transaction cost” effects, and “immigrant preference” effects.

3.1 Transaction cost effects#

Migrants are expected to stimulate trade by lowering transaction costs. There are two related sets of reasons why immigrants might face lower transaction costs for trade with their country of origin. The first is that immigrants have superior knowledge of home country markets, languages, business practices, laws, and other matters related to trade. The second is that migrants may be able to participate in international networks, as exemplified by the networks of ethnic Chinese (Rauch and Trindade 2002). These networks can be conduits of information, and can deter opportunistic behaviour.

Transaction cost effects are generally expected to stimulate both exports and imports. Most authors argue that migrants’ informational advantages are more important for differentiated goods than for homogenous goods, because of the greater information problems involved in the trade of differentiated goods. Most authors also argue that the trade-stimulating effect of migration is greatest when the host and origin countries have very different institutions, languages and cultures, and when alternative sources of information and contract enforcement are lacking, since this is when the special skills or migrants are most needed.

3.2 Immigrant preference effects#

Immigrants are assumed to demand certain goods produced in their home countries, or similar to those produced in their home countries. These preferences are expected to boost imports to the host country but not exports from the host country. The effect is assumed to be more marked for differentiated goods than for homogenous goods. Some authors note that there may be a countervailing “immigrant substitution” effect. If there are sufficient immigrants in a country, these immigrants may begin to produce goods themselves rather than importing them (Dunlevey and Hutchison 1999, Girma and Yu 2000).

4  Evidence on the activities of migrants in New Zealand#

Case studies in many countries show that “immigrants typically have found trading activities an accessible niche to fill in the labor market” (Gould 1994: 302), which is to be expected if migrants enjoy a transaction cost advantage. There is some survey evidence that migrants to New Zealand also use their backgrounds to facilitate international trade, as employees or as business owners.

Watts and Trlin (1999) sent questionnaires to 460 companies that they identified as being involved in foreign markets, and received replies from 187 (41%). Of these firms, 70% employed migrants from non-English speaking countries. Some, but not all, of the firms that employed migrants from non-English speaking countries used their employees’ linguistic skills and local knowledge. For instance, 58% used migrant employees for “assisting clients visiting NZ” and 42% for “translating documents”; 29% “indicated that they made use of the overseas contacts and networks of their employees” (Watts and Trlin 1999: 123-5).

Watts and Trlin also sent questionnaires to 156 immigrants from non-English speaking countries. Usable replies were received from 52 people (33%). Of the 52 people who replied, 41 were employed. Of these, 14 said that their cultural backgrounds were “relevant to their work activities” and seven “reported use of their business connections in their employment”. Over three-quarters of immigrants surveyed “were strongly of the opinion that their native-speaker skills in languages other than English and their cultural background could be used to better advantage in New Zealand”. Some respondents stated that their skills were under-used because of prejudice and discrimination (Watts and Trlin 1999: 124-8).

In 2002, the New Zealand Immigration Service surveyed Long-Term Business Visa and Investment Category migrants whose applications had been approved in 1999 and 2000 (New Zealand Immigration Service 2002). The Immigration Service attempted to locate 823 people, but made contact with only 84. Of the 59 businesses run by Long-Term Business Visa migrants, 43% were involved in importing, and 33% in exporting.[5] Thirteen out of 25 Investment Category migrants owned businesses. One of these businesses was involved in importing and five in exporting. The report states that “in most cases, investors were exporting to their country of birth” (New Zealand Immigration Service 2002: 106).

The low response rates and small sample sizes of these surveys mean that their results need to be treated cautiously. They do, nevertheless, suggest that the transaction cost theory, and the images of migrants involving themselves in international trade, have some empirical grounding.

Notes

  • [5]Calculated from data given in (New Zealand Immigration Service 2002: Tables 8.18, 8.19).  The calculations exclude the 11 businesses for which information on importing is not available, and the 12 for which information on exporting is not available.

5  Previous econometric tests of the effects of migration on trade#

Previous econometric tests of the effect of migration on trade have, like ours, been based on a gravity model of trade. The gravity model has been highly successful in describing empirical patterns of international trade (Frankel 1997). It can be derived in a number of different ways. Rauch (1999) and Head and Ries (1999) provide an intuitively appealing derivation, which we summarise here.

The derivation starts from a proposition about the pattern of trade in a frictionless world. Let

 

be the value of New Zealand’s imports from country

 

(the expression for New Zealand’s exports to country

 

is exactly symmetrical). Let

 

,

 

, and

 

be the GDPs of New Zealand, country

 

, and the world. In the absence of transport or transaction costs (and with some additional assumptions about product differentiation and preferences) New Zealand consumes the output of country

 

in proportion to New Zealand’s share of world output

 

, so that

 

(1)    

 

 

In practice, transport costs, tariffs, and transaction costs induce departures from this pattern. These effects are modelled by applying an adjustment factor

 

to the right hand side of Equation 1, where

 

is a vector that includes a range of variables attempting to capture transport and transaction costs. Taking logs yields the equation

 

(2)    

 

 

One variable that is almost always included is the distance between the two countries. The distance variable tries to measure transport and communication costs, but it is generally believed to pick up cultural, institutional, and linguistic differences as well. Transport and communication costs have fallen over time, but it is not clear how the impact of culture, institutions, and language have changed. Because the effect of distance is not a central concern of the paper, we decided to follow tradition and assume that the effect of distance is constant over time (though the use of time dummies, described below, provides some protection against any biases introduced by changes in the effect of distance.) Other frequently used variables include oil prices, real exchange rates, common languages, common borders, membership of trade blocs, and colonial ties. It has become standard to also include a population or a GDP per capita variable, to allow for effects such as subsistence thresholds or self-sufficiency.

For studies of migration and trade, the key variable in

 

is one measuring the number of migrants from each potential trading partner living in the country of interest. In principle, a variable measuring the number of migrants from the country of interest living in each potential trade partner country should also be used. The necessary data are, however, difficult to obtain. The only study to include such a variable is one on overseas Chinese (Rauch and Trindade 2002).

 

Table 2 summarises results from the nine previous econometric studies of migration and trade that we have located. The studies cover five host countries—the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, Spain, and France—and various trading partners, though in the case of Combes et al (2003) the trade in question is between different regions of France. Dunlevy and Hutchison (1999, 2001) use data from 1870 to 1910; all the other studies use more recent data. Some studies use data from a single period, while others use time series techniques to combine data from several periods. Some studies fit the model in its original multiplicative form using non-linear statistical models, and others take logs of both sides and use linear models.

The export and import elasticities in Table 2 show the extent to which an increase in the size of the immigrant stock increases trade. The elasticities derived by Gould (1994), for instance, imply that, all else equal, a 1% increase in the number of immigrants resident in a country would increase exports from that country by 0.02% and increase imports to that country by 0.01%. In cases where several specifications are presented, elasticities from the authors’ main or preferred elasticity are cited. Wherever possible, average elasticities across all goods and all trade partners are shown.

Table 2– The effect of migration on exports and imports, 9 studies
Study Sample Export elasticity Import elasticity
Gould (1994) US and 47 trade partners; 1970-1986 0.02 0.01
Head and Ries (1998) Canada and 136 trade partners; 1980-1992 0.10 0.31
Dunlevy and Hutchinson (1999, 2001) US and 17 trade partners; 1870-1910 0.08 0.29
Girma and Yu (2000) UK and 48 trade partners; 1981-1993 0.02 -0.04
Combes et al (2002) 95 French Departments; 1993 0.25 0.14
Rauch and Trindade (2002) 63 Countries; 1980, 1990 0.21/0.47a 0.21/0.47a
Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002) 5 Canadian regions and 160 foreign countries; 1992-1995 0.08 0.25
Blanes-Cristobal (2003) Spain and 40 trade partners, 1991-1998 0.23 0.03
Ching and Chen (2000) Canada and Taiwan -0.06b 0.30b

aThe estimate of 0.21 applies to homogenous goods, and 0.47 to differentiated goods; insufficient data were included in the article to allow the calculation of an overall elasticity. No distinction is made between imports and exports. bExport elasticity refers to exports from Canada to Taiwan, import elasticity refers to exports from Taiwan to Canada.

Notes – Rows 1-6 are based on Table 1 in Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002). The elasticities for Gould (1994) and Rauch and Trindade (2002) were calculated by Wagner et al. The elasticities for Girma and Yu (2000) and Ching and Chen (2000) were calculated by the present authors.

As is apparent from Table 2, most studies find some relationship between migration and trade, in the expected direction, though the magnitudes of the estimated effects vary greatly. All the studies shown in Table 2 also investigate how the relationship between migration and trade varies across goods, countries or the type of migrant. Gould (1994) and Dunlevy and Hutchinson (1999, 2001), for instance, find that the effect of migrants is stronger for consumer goods than producer goods. Rauch and Trindade (2002) and Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002) find that the effect is stronger for differentiated goods than for homogenous goods. Girma and Yu (2000) find that the effect is stronger when there are no colonial ties; Blanes-Cristobal (2003) obtains the opposite result. Ching and Chen (2000) find that the effect is stronger for entrepreneur rather than passive investment type migrants.

Gould (1994: 307) and Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002: 520-22) experiment with alternative specifications in which the elasticity of trade with respect to migration changes as the number of migrants increases. They find that the elasticity decreases with the number of migrants. This is a very strong form of diminishing returns. Diminishing returns in the ordinary sense of each migrant contributing less than the one before is already possible under the constant-elasticity specification[6].

All the studies summarised in Table 2 looked at trade in goods rather than services. We know of no studies that have looked at the effect of migrant stocks on exports of services, even though migration could plausibly lower transaction costs for trade in services in the same way that it lowers costs for trade in goods.

Notes

  • [6]Let m  be trade and x migration.  There are diminishing returns when m″ 0.

6  Methodology#

6.1  Data#

We have assembled data for a large panel of countries for every year from 1981 to 2001. The minimum number of countries included in the panel in our benchmark specifications is 171; the maximum is 179. We include substantially more observations than any previous studies of trade and migration, with the exception of Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002). As discussed below, the reason for assembling a large panel dataset is to address problems of unobserved heterogeneity and selection bias.

Our data on imports and exports come from the United Nations Statistics Division’s Comtrade Database. The UN obtains estimates of New Zealand imports and exports from Statistics New Zealand. We treat the data as complete. If no trade is reported between New Zealand and a given country in a given year, we assume that the true value for that year was zero.

Estimates of the foreign-born population in New Zealand come from unpublished tabulations prepared by Statistics New Zealand using data from the 1981, 1986, 1991, 1996, and 2001 Censuses. To calculate exact values for the inter-censal years it would be necessary to have data on deaths and international movements by place of birth, which are not available. An alternative would be to interpolate. We decided, however, to use the total from the most recent Census for the whole inter-censal period, so that, for instance, migrant stock in years 1981, 1982, 1983, 1984, and 1985 is set equal to the Census estimate in 1981. The advantage of this method, besides its simplicity, is that it gives partial protection against the possibility that migration is responding (in the short term) to trade.

Data on New Zealand’s GDP and population come from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators database. Data on language come from Grimes (1996), and distance from New Zealand from the website Great Circle Distances Between Capital Cities.[7]

6.2  Unobserved heterogeneity[8]#

The variables available to us cannot possibly capture all influences on New Zealand’s trade. In other words, there is likely to be unobserved heterogeneity across our sample. Applying ordinary cross-sectional techniques in the presence of unobserved heterogeneity can lead to incorrect standard errors and biased coefficient estimates.

Use of panel data, however, permits models of the form

(3)    

 

 

where

 

is a time-varying idiosyncratic error, and

 

is an unobserved country-specific effect that represents the permanent cross-country heterogeneity. If the

 

are assumed to be uncorrelated with the explanatory variables, then Equation 3 can be estimated using a Random Effects approach. The assumption of zero correlation is, however, difficult to justify in our case. No such assumption is required under a Fixed Effects approach. Under Fixed Effects, however, it is not possible to obtain coefficients for variables that are constant over time, such as Language and Distance.

 

Previous econometric studies of migration and trade have used either ordinary cross-sectional techniques or Fixed Effects. There is, however, an alternative approach, referred to as Correlated Random Effects, that avoids the zero correlation assumption and allows the inclusion of variables that are fixed over time. Under Correlated Random Effects, the correlation between the country-specific fixed effect

 

and the explanatory variables is explicitly modelled using the expression

 

(4)    

 

 

where the

 

are vectors of “projection coefficients” and

 

is a true random effect that is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables. We assign the same weight to all time periods, so that

 

(5)    

 

,

 

and

(6)    

 

.

 

Substituting this expression into Equation 3 (and absorbing

 

, a constant, into

 

) gives

 

(7)    

 

,

 

which can be estimated using Random Effects.

Some unobserved heterogeneity also potentially takes the form of shocks affecting New Zealand’s trade with all countries more or less equally at the same time. An important example is the trade liberalisation that New Zealand began in the mid-1980s (Evans, Grimes, Wilkinson and Teece 1996). We allow for such affects by adding a time dummy for the period 1995 to 2001 to all equations.

6.3  Sample selection#

Equation 7 does not allow for zero trade. In practice, however, 29% of our observations for imports are zeros, as are 20% of our observations for exports. Following previous studies of migration and trade, we interpret the zeros to mean that observed trade values emerge from a two-step process. Countries in effect decide whether to trade, and then decide how much to trade (Head and Ries 1998; Dunlevy and Hutchinson 1999: fn20; Wagner, Head, and Ries 2002: 518). Our model is

(8a)     

 

 

(8b)     

 

 

(9)    

 

 

We assume that

 

and are non-autocorrelated, and that

 

, with a correlation,

 

, between the two that may not equal zero. Equations 8a and 8b together make up the “selection equation,” while Equation 9 is the trade equation. If the correlation between the two error terms is not zero, then simply using Equation 7 on the sub-sample with non-zero trade will lead to biased estimates.

 

As explained in LIMDEP (Version 8.0), this sample selection model can be estimated as a random parameters model by treating

 

and

 

as random coefficients. We adopt this approach and estimate the model in two steps by maximum simulated likelihood method. We first fit a random parameters probit model and store the results for use in the next phase where we fit the trade equation.

 

Following previous studies, we use the log of migrant numbers in

 

. In some cases, however, the number of migrants equals zero, so that the log is undefined. Simply omitting these cases could potentially create a selection bias. We therefore adopt an approach used by Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002). We introduce a dummy variable called Zero Migrants that takes a value of one when there are no migrants, and zero otherwise. We set our Migrant Stock variable equal to zero when there are no migrants, and the log of the number of migrants otherwise. The Zero Migrants variable shows the change in trade that occurs when New Zealand has exactly one migrant from a country rather than none. In principle, it should be close to zero.

 

Notes

  • [7]Available at: http://www.wcrl.ars.usda.gov/cec/java/capitals.htm
  • [8]This section draws heavily on unpublished lecture notes by Dean Hyslop.

6.4  Differences in the characteristics of goods and countries#

Theory suggests, and empirical studies largely confirm, that the effect of migration on trade varies with the goods being traded and the countries involved. We intend to carry out detailed analyses of differences between types of goods in future work. In the present paper, we simply look at the effect of excluding certain goods for which the effect of migrants is likely to be small. We re-estimate our results using exports excluding agriculture. The reason for excluding agriculture is that most of New Zealand’s international agricultural exports are channelled through a few large companies, which presumably are large enough to recruit internationally if they cannot draw on local migrants. We also re-estimate our results using imports excluding oil, on the grounds that imports are channelled through a few large companies, and also because petroleum products are homogeneous goods which pose fewer of the transactional difficulties that migrants are expected to alleviate. Our expectation is that the coefficients on the migration variables should be larger in the specifications excluding agriculture and oil than they are in the benchmark specifications.

As with previous studies, we hypothesise that migrants have a stronger effect on trade when they come from a non-English-speaking country, because the migrants’ language skills are then needed, and because language proxies for cultural and institutional differences from New Zealand. We test for such effects by interacting the migrant variable with the language variable. We also hypothesise that migrants have a stronger effect when they come from a low-income country (having controlled for the size of the countries’ GDPs), since low income proxies for cultural and institutional differences, and for difficulties in obtaining information and enforcing contracts. We test for this by interacting the migrant variable with a low-income variable.

6.5  Changes in elasticity with the size of the migration stock#

We examine how the size of the migrant stock affects the elasticity of trade with respect to migration. We do this by adding the square of our migrant variable to the regressions. This is equivalent to assuming that the elasticity of trade with respect to migration declines linearly with the log of the number of migrants. This assumption is somewhat arbitrary and has the unrealistic implication that the elasticity will eventually become negative in many cases. As discussed in Section 4, Gould (1994: 307) and Wagner, Head, and Ries (2002: 520-22) use alternative, more complicated, expressions. Gould’s coefficients are, however, difficult to interpret. The coefficients in Wagner et al’s expression have a clear interpretation, but it is not feasible to estimate them as part of a selection model.

6.6  Migrant stocks and tourism#

As discussed in Section 4, previous studies of the effect of migration on trade have looked exclusively at merchandise trade. We examine the effect of stocks on an important component of the international services trade: tourism.

Ideally, we would like to use data on expenditure by overseas visitors. Unfortunately, such data are only available for a small subset of origin countries. Comprehensive data are, however, available on the number of visitors arriving from each country. We therefore use visitor numbers to proxy for expenditures. Most visits to New Zealand are for tourism or similar purposes: in the year to March 2004, 51% of visitors stated that their reason for visiting was “tourism/holiday” and a further 28% stated that it was to “visit friends/relatives”.[9]

Census respondents are recorded as “usually resident”, and hence included in our foreign-born measures, only if they answer yes to a question asking whether they live in New Zealand. Some short-term visitors may, however, misinterpret the question and be inappropriately included. This would bias upwards our estimates of the effect of migration on visitor flows. The help sheets accompanying the 1996 and 2001 Census forms explicitly stated people should not answer yes to the residency question unless they were in New Zealand for more than a year. We re-run our model using data from the 1996-2002 period alone to see whether this affects our results.

6.7  Additional robustness testing#

To examine the sensitivity of our results to the sample chosen, we run the model on several different sub-samples of countries. We split the sample into English and non-English speaking countries and high income and low income countries. We also examine the effect of simply omitting countries with no migrants, rather than using the Zero Migrant variable.

We have not included a real exchange rate variable in most of our regressions, as the necessary data are available for only about half of our sample. To assess whether the omission of the exchange rate variable is likely to have affected our results, we apply our benchmark specification to the sub-sample, and then recalculate using the real exchange rate variable.

6.8  Variables#

Table 3 summarises the variables. The sources of our data are discussed in Section 6.1.

Table 3– Variables used in the models
Variable name Definition
Migrant Stock Log of the number of migrants at the time of the most recent Census.
Zero Migrants Dummy variable taking a value of one if there are no migrants from the country
Foreign GDP Log of a foreign country’s GDP (in 1995 $US)
New Zealand GDP Log of New Zealand’s GDP (in 1995 $US)
World GDP Log of World’s GDP
Population Log of a foreign country’s population
Distance Log of the distance between the foreign country’s capital and Wellington
Non-English A dummy variable taking a value of one if English is not widely spoken in the country.
Average Migrant Stock The average value over time of the Migrant Stock variable
Average Foreign GDP The average value over time of the Foreign GDP variable
Average Population The average value over time of the Population variable
1995 Dummy A dummy variable taking a value of one if the year is between 1995 and 2001
Square of Migrant Stock The square of the Migrant Stock variable.  Note that the variable is squared after taking logs, not before.
Migrant Stock x Low income Equal to Migrant Stock if the country is classified as low or middle income by the World Bank, and zero otherwise
Migrant Stock x Non-English Equal to Migrant Stock if Non-English equals one, and zero otherwise

Notes

  • [9]Estimates taken from Statistics New Zealand External Migration (March 2004) - Hot Off The Press, from the Statistics New Zealand website www.stats.govt.nz.

7  Results#

All results presented throughout this section are generated using Correlated Random Effects models. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all specifications. We do not, however, present the coefficients from these. We use one, two and three stars (*) to denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively. P-values on many of our variables fluctuate between 0.01 and 0.10.

7.1  Benchmark results#

In Table 4 we report our benchmark results. As described in Section 6, the variables Average Migrant Stock, Average GDP and Average Population capture correlations between the explanatory variables and country-specific effects.

In the selection equation for exports the estimated coefficients on Zero Migrants, Foreign GDP, New Zealand GDP, World GDP and Non-English are all positive and highly significant, indicating that, all else equal, higher values for these variables imply a higher probability that trade between New Zealand and a given country takes place. The size of the increment in the probability depends on the country’s characteristics. As discussed in Section 6.3, we had expected the coefficient on Zero Migrants to be close to zero. However, the fact that it is not probably reveals more about the idiosyncrasies of the countries with zero reported migrants than it does about the relationship between migration and trade. The estimated coefficients on Population, Distance and the 1995 Dummy are all negative and highly significant indicating that, all else equal, higher values for these variables would on average result in a lower probability that trade between New Zealand and a given country takes place. The coefficient estimate on Migrant Stock, the variable of most interest to us in this study, is positive and highly significant.

In the trade equation for exports the estimated coefficients on Foreign GDP, New Zealand GDP, World GDP and the 1995 Dummy are positive while the estimated coefficients on Zero Migrants, Population, Distance and Non-English are negative. As Foreign GDP, New Zealand GDP, World GDP, Population and Distance are in logs the estimated coefficients associated with these variables are simple elasticities. The coefficient on Foreign GDP of 0.9492 for example implies that, all else equal, increasing a country’s GDP by 1% would lead to a 0.95% increase in exports to that country. For dummy variables such as our 1995 Dummy, a coefficient value of

 

implies that, all else equal, exports to that country will be

 

% higher when the dummy variable equals one.[10] The coefficient of 0.1358 on our 1995 Dummy implies that, all else equal, New Zealand would have exported approximately 14% more to any given country in the period between 1995 and 2001 than in the period between 1981 and 1994.

 

Table 4 – Benchmark results
Variable Exports Imports
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.3965*** (0.0365) 0.0868***(0.0165) 0.0698* (0.0358) 0.1502*** (0.023)
Zero Migrants 0.5834*** (0.0882) -0.0694 (0.0477) 0.2434*** (0.0875) -0.119 (0.0767)
Foreign GDP 0.6156*** (0.0935) 0.9492*** (0.0496) -0.2882*** (0.0894) 1.4093*** (0.0725)
New Zealand GDP 3.0479*** (0.8156) 0.5681 (0.3518) 3.0521*** (0.7234) 1.97*** (0.4778)
World GDP 4.2137*** (0.4859) 0.3791* (0.2103) -0.2424 (0.4217) -0.6098** (0.2812)
Population -3.7372*** (0.2574) -0.5804*** (0.109) -0.1762 (0.2269) -0.5977*** (0.1358)
Distance -2.062*** (0.1483) -2.3297*** (0.0345) -2.1738*** (0.129) -1.3301*** (0.0429)
Non-English 0.1747 (0.0672) -0.2556*** (0.03) 1.23*** (0.0628) -0.2419*** (0.0393)
Average Migrant Stock -0.168*** (0.0359) 0.2454*** (0.0174) 0.4238*** (0.0389) 0.2571*** (0.0243)
Average Foreign GDP 0.4447*** (0.0995) -0.1813*** (0.0509) 0.7991*** (0.0953) -0.1264* (0.0735)
Average Population 3.0164*** (0.2552) 0.5326*** (0.1092) -0.1539 (0.2294) 0.2572* (0.1368)
1995 Dummy -0.444*** (0.119) 0.1358*** (0.0479) 0.0377 (0.1097) -0.0367 (0.0632)
Log Likelihood -769.6441 -6232.3420 -923.8712 -5824.903
Observations 3385 2721 3385 2406
Countries 179 176 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions. Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars. Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

The estimated coefficient on Migrant Stock is highly significant. It implies that on average a 1% increase in the stock of migrants from a given country would result in an increase in exports to that country of around 0.09%.

In the selection equation for imports the estimated coefficient on Migrant stock suggests that increasing the number of migrants from a given country will, all else equal, increase the probability that New Zealand imports from that country. Migrant Stock is statistically significant at the 10 percent level.

In the trade equation for imports the estimated coefficient on Migrant Stock is highly significant and implies that, on average, a 1% increase in the stock of migrants from a given country would result in an increase in imports from that country of around 0.15%.

In Section 6.4 we hypothesise that the effect of migrants on trade may vary depending on the type of good traded. To investigate this we present in Table 5 our results when excluding agriculture from exports and oil from imports.

Notes

  • [10]Let m1 be predicted exports when the dummy variable equals 1, and m0 predicted exports when the dummy variable equals 0.  Then lnm1 - lnm0  = β, m1 / m1 – 1 = eβ – 1 ≈ (1 + β) – 1 = β.  This approximation ceases to be accurate if the absolute value of β is large.

7.1  Benchmark results (continued)#

Table 5– Benchmark results, excluding agriculture and oil
Variable Exports (Excluding Agriculture) Imports (Excluding Oil)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.3168*** (0.0251) 0.1365*** (0.0368) 0.0784** (0.0187) >0.2223*** (0.0343)
Zero Migrants 0.3163*** (0.0796) 0.5876*** (0.0829) 0.2712*** (0.0875) 0.0544 (0.0666)
Foreign GDP 0.2301*** (0.0732) 1.2235*** (0.054) -0.3085*** (0.0897) 1.497*** (0.0666)
New Zealand GDP 0.9061 (0.7669) -1.7969*** (0.458) 2.9894*** (0.7083) 2.3288*** (0.4265)
World GDP 2.4103*** (0.4419) 0.7683*** (0.2457) -0.0108 (0.4242) -0.5856** (0.2395)
Population -0.7502*** (0.194) 0.8398*** (0.1405) -0.2379 (0.2346) -0.5861*** (0.1237)
Distance -1.7725*** (0.1373) -2.1972*** (0.042) -1.9731*** (0.1256) -0.9596*** (0.0374)
Non-English 0.0794 (0.0622) 0.3262*** (0.0375) 1.1437*** (0.0608) -0.3814*** (0.0352)
Average Migrant Stock 0.012 (0.0342) 0.425*** (0.0268) 0.4162*** (0.0394) 0.3232*** (0.0203)
Average Foreign GDP 0.5525*** (0.0808) -0.3884*** (0.0557) 0.7413*** (0.0952) -0.6645*** (0.0673)
Average Population 0.101 (0.1964) -1.2046*** (0.1408) -0.0201 (0.2368) 0.7015*** (0.1248)
1995 Dummy -0.0845 (0.1166) 0.3232*** (0.0678) 0.0131 (0.107) -0.1425** (0.0573)
Log Likelihood -894.3868 -6036.8670 -948.6351 -5549.9280
Observations 3385 2574 3385 2388
Countries 179 175 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions. Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars. Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

As expected the effect of these exclusions is to increase the coefficient estimates on Migrant Stock in the trade equations for both exports (excluding agriculture) and imports (excluding oil).

7.2  Extensions#

We now examine whether the effect of migration varies by type of country, and we test for the effect of migration on tourism exports.

Table 6– Allowing the effect of migrants to vary by language
Variable Exports Imports
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.3444***(0.0378) 0.1064***(0.0171) 0.0076(0.0381) 0.2125***(0.0251)
Migrant Stock x Non-English 0.0682**(0.0267) -0.0569***(0.0099) 0.1103***(0.0245) -0.0779***(0.0138)
Zero Migrants 0.5824***(0.0922) -0.2358***(0.049) 0.3294***(0.0914) -0.1434*(0.08)
Foreign GDP 0.6023***(0.0921) 0.9573***(0.0507) -0.297***(0.0896) 1.4258***(0.073)
New Zealand GDP 3.048***(0.8134) 0.5171(0.354) 3.0609***(0.7271) 1.9893***(0.4815)
World GDP 4.1159***(0.4852) 0.4474**(0.21) -0.3396(0.4252) -0.6429**(0.2818)
Population -3.6561***(0.2545) -0.6495***(0.1092) -0.0825(0.2272) -0.6279***(0.1363)
Distance -2.6439***(0.1587) -2.782***(0.0357) -2.2619***(0.131) -1.0345***(0.0428)
Non-English 0.2225*(0.1253) 0.4058***(0.057) 0.7494***(0.1186) -0.0038(0.0832)
Average Migrant Stock -0.1056***(0.0354) 0.2543***(0.0174) 0.4119***(0.0388) 0.2695***(0.0248)
Average Foreign GDP 0.2551***(0.0975) -0.0147(0.0521) 0.8155***(0.0959) -0.1054(0.0741)
Average Population 3.023***(0.2517) 0.375***(0.1092) -0.2161(0.2293) 0.2367*(0.1371)
1995 Dummy -0.438***(0.1188) 0.1437***(0.0482) 0.041(0.1096) -0.0389(0.0635)
Log Likelihood -770.1116 -6230.1140 -922.6665 -5825.5810
Observations 3385 2721 3385 2406
Countries 179 176 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions. Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars. Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

Table 6 presents our results for both export and import equations when we allow interaction between our Migrant Stock and Non-English variables. If migrants from Non-English speaking countries have a greater effect on trade than migrants from English speaking countries then we should see positive coefficient estimates on our interaction variable, Migrant Stock x Non-English. In the selection equations for both exports and imports, migrants from Non-English speaking countries increase the probability that trade will take place between New Zealand and a given country by more than migrants from English speaking countries. The effect of migrants from Non-English speaking countries in both trade equations is however less than that of migrants from English speaking countries. The overall impact on trade of English versus Non-English speaking migrants is therefore unclear. This may in large part be an artefact of the choice of our language variable which classes over 80 countries as being English speaking.

Table 7– Allowing elasticity to change with the number of migrants
Variable Exports Imports
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.7079***(0.0545) 0.0997***(0.0225) 0.346***(0.0533) 0.4909***(0.0296)
Square of Migrant Stock -0.0529***(0.0057) -0.0031*(0.0016) -0.0407***(0.005) -0.0344***(0.0021)
Zero Migrants 0.9479***(0.1106) -0.0903(0.0574) 0.6587***(0.1107) 0.3748***(0.0864)
Foreign GDP 0.6087***(0.0912) 0.9415***(0.0507) -0.2724***(0.0889) 1.5607***(0.0727)
New Zealand GDP 2.9717***(0.8099) 0.6856*(0.3593) 3.2462***(0.463) 1.7308***(0.2914)
World GDP 4.0465***(0.4825) 0.33(0.2168) -0.2892(0.3915) -0.447*(0.2455)
Population -3.4344***(0.2576) -0.5923***(0.1097) -0.096(0.231) -0.8456***(0.1387)
Distance -1.9193***(0.1451) -2.5103***(0.0358) -1.979***(0.1233) -1.4863***(0.0426)
Non-English -0.4712***(0.0662) 0.2702***(0.0305) 0.9189***(0.0617) -0.9885***(0.039)
Average Migrant Stock 0.016(0.035) 0.2391***(0.0169) 0.4473***(0.0388) 0.1866***(0.0243)
Average Foreign GDP 0.0914(0.0961) 0.1298**(0.0528) 0.8414***(0.0953) -0.2699***(0.0738)
Average Population 2.9869***(0.2558) 0.1868*(0.1098) -0.2208(0.2335) 0.6054***(0.1397)
1995 Dummy -0.4358***(0.1187) 0.1329***(0.0483) --- ---
Log Likelihood -768.2800 -6230.6340 -919.4301 -5823.4070
Observations 3385 2721 3385 2406
Countries 179 176 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions. Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars. Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

We repeat our analysis excluding agriculture exports and oil imports in Appendix Table 2. The effect of excluding these goods is to increase the coefficient estimates on the interaction term in both the trade equations to the point where the coefficient estimate for imports is positive and significant. The interaction term in the selection equation for exports is however no longer significant. We also allow the effect of migrants to vary with the income of the country from which they were born in. These results are presented in Appendix Table 3 and Appendix Table 4.

In Table 7 we allow for the possibility that the effect of migrants on trade varies with the number of migrants from a given country. We do this by including the square of our Migrant Stock variable. The estimated coefficient on this variable is negative in all four equations indicating that there are decreasing returns to migrants. The effects are weaker when we exclude agricultural goods and oil from exports and imports respectively. See Appendix Table 5.

7.2  Extensions (continued)#

Table 8– The effect of migration on tourism exports
Variable Tourism Exports (Model One) Tourism Exports (Model Two)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.0258(0.0315) 0.1497***(0.0069) 0.1144**(0.0554) -0.1356***(0.0126)
Square of Migrant Stock --- --- -0.0139**(0.0063) 0.0299***(0.0009)
Zero Migrants -0.1516*(0.0906) 0.3354***(0.0289) -0.0282(0.1238) -0.0947***(0.0368)
Foreign GDP -0.1202(0.081) 0.7486***(0.0181) -0.1157(0.0808) 0.6682***(0.0192)
New Zealand GDP 2.1971***(0.6395) -0.8074***(0.2071) 2.1788***(0.6386) -0.78***(0.2068)
World GDP -0.6753*(0.3517) 2.9059***(0.1164) -0.659*(0.3515) 2.7892***(0.1154)
Population -1.5997***(0.2077) -1.2965***(0.0504) -1.5759***(0.2081) -1.0868***(0.0505)
Distance -1.6997***(0.119) -2.3758***(0.0183) -1.6799***(0.1184) -2.1694***(0.0185)
Non-English -0.7066***(0.0595) 0.0339**(0.016) -0.6821***(0.0597) -0.1783***(0.0158)
Average Migrant Stock 0.1981***(0.0326) 0.1508***(0.0079) 0.2248***(0.033) 0.1786***(0.0085)
Average Foreign GDP 0.662***(0.0885) 0.1653***(0.0191) 0.645***(0.0884) 0.1443***(0.0203)
Average Population 1.2887***(0.2092) 0.7824***(0.0506) 1.2739***(0.2095) 0.6941***(0.0508)
1995 Dummy 0.3309***(0.0964) 0.1518***(0.0286) 0.33***(0.0963) 0.1454***(0.0285)
Log Likelihood -976.3704 -4087.906 -976.0179 -4063.990
Observations 3385 2645 3385 2645
Countries 179 178 179 178

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3. A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions. Dependent variables are short term visitor flows to New Zealand during any given year. Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

In Table 8 we use short term visitor flows to proxy for tourism exports. It is evident from the table that migrants have a strong positive effect on tourism exports. There is evidence to suggest that this effect increases as the number of migrants from a given country increases.

Because there was a change to the way in which migrants were counted in the 1996 census that may influence these results, we repeat our analysis in Appendix Table 6 for the period 1996 to 2001. See section 6.6 for further details. The estimated coefficients on Migrant Stock for this period are somewhat larger.

7.3  Additional robustness testing#

To investigate the robustness of our results we have tried splitting up our sample by High and Low income countries and by English and Non-English speaking countries. The effect of splitting our sample by language is that the estimated coefficients on Migrant Stock fall as compared to our benchmark results, and vary markedly between English and Non-English speaking countries (with the estimated coefficients on Migrant Stock actually being higher for Non-English speaking countries). When we split our sample by income the estimated coefficients are similar to those we present in Table 4.

We have also tried excluding from our regressions all countries from which New Zealand has no migrants. The effect of this on our estimated coefficients for Migrant Stock is negligible.

We include in Appendix Tables 7 and 8 a comparison of our benchmark results when we include the log of the real exchange rate in our regressions against the same sample when the real exchange rate variable is excluded. The effect of excluding the real exchange rate term on our coefficient estimates on Migrant Stock is negligible. The coefficients are, however, considerably higher than our benchmark results presented in Table 4. This again shows the sensitivity of our results to sample selection and may help account for the variety in the predicted effects of migrants on trade in other studies.

8  Discussion#

Results from our benchmark specification strongly suggest that the more migrants New Zealand receives from a given country, the more likely it is that New Zealand exports to that country, controlling for plausible confounding factors such as GDP, language, population, and distance. Similarly, the results strongly suggest that if New Zealand does export to a country, then an increase in migrants from that country is associated with an increase in exports. Results for imports are slightly different. There is some support for the idea that more migrants are associated with a greater probability of importing, and strong support for the idea that more migration is associated with higher imports. Taken at face value the results imply that if New Zealand does import from a country, a 1% increase in migrants is associated with a 0.15% increase in imports.

Following previous studies, we attribute any relationship between migration and exports to the ability of migrants to reduce transaction costs. We attribute the relationship between migration and imports to some unknown mix of transaction cost effects and preferences by migrants for goods from their country of origin. In most of our specifications it appears as though the relationship between migration and trade is strongest for imports. This suggests that the preferences of migrants may well be important, but could also be due to the goods that New Zealand imports being more differentiated in general than those New Zealand exports.

Using international visitor numbers as a proxy for earnings, we use the same specification to test for a relationship between migration and tourism “exports”. The relationship appears to be strong. However, some of this apparent strength is probably an artefact of some short-term visitors being recorded as long-term migrants.

Some variants on the benchmark case for merchandise exports and imports give results that are consistent with the hypothesis that migration stimulates trade. We expected that migration would have less effect on transaction costs and hence trade for agricultural exports and oil imports. It turns out that excluding agriculture and oil do indeed yield stronger relationships. A possible objection to our benchmark specification is that it does not include a real exchange rate variable. We applied our benchmark specification on the sub-sample for which the necessary data were available, and then added in the exchange rate variable. Adding the exchange rate variable made little difference to the results.

Experiments with interaction terms yielded some results that were inconsistent with the transaction cost interpretation. We had expected that the relationship between migration and trade would be stronger for migrants from non-English speaking countries than from English-speaking countries. When there are language differences and associated cultural and institutional differences, migrants’ potential contribution to facilitating trade is presumably greatest. The regression results suggest that the relationship between migration and the probability of trading is stronger for non-English speaking countries than for English speaking countries, we obtain the opposite result for our trade equations. We had also expected that the relationship between migration and trade would be stronger for migrants from low income countries than for high income countries (controlling for the independent effect of economic size), on the grounds that low income proxies for differences in culture and institutions. Again, the regression results were contrary to our expectations.

Other results make it difficult to be confident about the magnitude of the association between migration and trade. The experiment with the real exchange rate variable indicates that the results are sensitive to the choice of sample. The experiment with the square of the Migrant Stock term suggests that the elasticity of trade with respect to migration varies with the size of the migrant stock. We are not, however, satisfied that the squared term captures this relationship adequately.

It should be possible, in future work, to reduce some of the remaining uncertainties. We aim to disaggregate imports and exports by commodity type. As well as potentially generating further insights into the effects of migration, results from a disaggregated analysis can be used to test the prediction that migrants stimulate trade in differentiated goods more than homogenous goods. We will also experiment with specifications that allow elasticities to vary with the number of migrants.

In the meantime, our judgement is that migration to New Zealand does increase New Zealand’s trade with the migrants’ origin counties. We base this judgement on the fact that positive and significant associations occur in all our specifications, and in all overseas studies, and because the underlying theory is plausible. We are, however, uncertain about the strength of the relationship.

If migration does boost trade, what are the implications? When imports increase because of immigrant preference effects, standard welfare economics can say very little on whether this is good or bad. The situation is essentially the same as a change in the composition of demand due to a shift in preferences. In contrast, an increase in imports or exports brought about by a reduction in transaction costs must be welfare-enhancing. It is analogous to an increase in imports or exports brought about by a fall in shipping costs. A fall in costs allows New Zealanders to realise more gains from international trade. Any reduction in transaction costs can alternatively be viewed as a reduction in the effective distance between New Zealand and the rest of the world. New Zealand’s remoteness, combined with its small size, is often argued to be a serious handicap to the economy, so such effects are potentially important.

It would be easier, and safer, to draw policy implications when results of the analysis by commodity group are available. More satisfactory modelling of the relationship between numbers of migrants and the elasticity of trade with respect to migration would also reduce uncertainty about the strength of the effect. A provisional conclusion, however, is that immigration policies may need to be judged by their implications for trade, in addition to their implications for labour supply and human capital.


References#

Blanes-Cristóbal, José Vicente (2003) "The link between immigration and trade in spain." Seville, Universidad Pablo de Olavide, Paper presented at XXVIII Simposio de Análisis Económico, 11-13 December, Seville. >

Bryant, John and David Law (2004) "New Zealand's diaspora and overseas-born population." Wellington, New Zealand Treasury, Working Paper No 04/13.

Ching, Hsianghoo S and Li-Lu Chen (2000) "Links between emigrants and the home country: The case of trade between taiwan and Canada." in Hirotada Kohno, Peter Nijkamp and Jacques Poot eds Regional cohesion and competition in the age of globalization (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar): 185-198.

Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Miren Lafourcade and Thierry Mayer (2003) "Can business and social networks explain the border effect puzzle?" Paris, Centre d'Etudes Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales (CEPII), Working Paper No 2003-02. http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/workpap/pdf/2003/wp03-02.pdf>

Dunlevey, James A and William K Hutchison (1999) "The impact of immigration on American import trade in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries." Journal of Economic History December: 1043-1062.

Evans, Lewis, Arthur Grimes, Bryce Wilkinson and David Teece (1996) "Economic reform in New Zealand 1984-95: The pursuit of efficiency." Journal of Economic Literature 34(4): 1856-1902.

Frankel, J A (1997) Regionalization of the world economy. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

Girma, Sourafel and Zhihao Yu (2000) "The link between immigration and trade: Evidence from the UK." Nottingham, University of Nottingham, Centre for Research on Globalisation and Labour Markets, Research Paper No 2000/23. http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/economics/leverhulme/research_papers/00_23.pdf>

Gould, David M (1994) "Immigrant links to the home country: Empirical implications for US bilateral trade flows." Review of Economics and Statistics 76(2): 302-316.

Grimes, Barbara F ed (1996) Ethnologue: Languages of the world (13th ed). (Dallas TX: Summer Institute of Linguistics)

Head, Keith and John Ries (1998) "Immigration and trade creation: Econometric evidence from Canada." Canadian Journal of Economics 31(1): 47-62.

Hutchinson, William K (2001) "The pro-trade effect of immigration on American exports during period 1870 to 1910." Nashville TN, Vanderbilt University, Department of Economics Working Paper No 01-W25. http://www.vanderbilt.edu/Econ/wparchive/workpaper/vu01-w25.pdf>

Lidgard, Jacqueline, Richard Bedford and Joanne Goodwin (1998) "Transformations in New Zealand's international migration system: 1981-1996." Hamilton, University of Waikato, Population Studies Centre, Discussion Paper No 25.

New Zealand Immigration Service (2002) "Business immigration: The evaluation of the 1999 business immigration policy." Wellington, Department of Labour, Immigration Research Programme. http://www.dol.govt.nz/publication-view.asp?ID=163>

Rauch, James E (1999) "Networks versus markets in international trade." Journal of International Economics 48(1): 7-35.

Rauch, James E and Vitor Trindade (2002) "Ethnic chinese networks in international trade." Review of Economics and Statistics 84(1): 116-130.

Wagner, Don, Keith Head and John Ries (2002) "Immigration and the trade of provinces." Scottish Journal of Political Economy 49(5): 507-525.

Watts, Noel and Andrew Trlin (1999) "Cultural resources of immigrants and international business in New Zealand." New Zealand Population Review 25: 119-132.

Appendix – Supplementary data and estimation results#

Appendix Table 1– Changes in New Zealand’s migrant stock, exports excluding agriculture, and imports excluding oil, by region, 1981-2001
  Population by region of birth (thousands) Exports excluding agriculture by region (NZ$1995 millions) Imports excluding oil by region  (NZ$1995 millions)
1981 2001 Incr. 1981 2001 Incr. 1981 2001 Incr.
Australia 44 56 28% 1,165 3,990 242% 1,253 4,926 293%
East Asia & Pacific 76 253 233% 1,591 5,060 218% 1,942 7,213 271%
Europe & Central Asia 47 67 42% 782 1,009 29% 895 4,227 372%
Mid East & N Africa 2 12 679% 144 157 9% 12 369 3035%
North America 12 21 81% 467 2,253 382% 1,680 4,504 168%
South America 2 4 74% 22 224 915% 60 327 448%
South Asia 7 31 313% 110 173 58% 62 244 292%
Sub-Saharan Africa 8 36 381% 22 73 227% 28 120 325%
United Kingdom 253 217 -14% 243 498 105% 767 1,003 31%
Unspecified 14 149 979% 359 451 26% 121 675 460%
New Zealand 2,679 2,891 8% - - - - - -
Total 3,143 3,737 19% 4,906 13,888 183% 6,819 23,607 246%

Source – Population data from Statistics New Zealand unpublished census tabulations. Trade estimates calculated from the United Nations Statistics Division’s Comtrade database.  The original Comtrade data were denominated in US dollars.  For a description of the conversion to NZ dollars, see Section 2.

Appendix Table 2 – Allowing the effect of migrants to vary by language, excluding agriculture and oil
Variable Exports (Excluding Agriculture) Imports (Excluding Oil)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.337***(0.0371) 0.1481***(0.0266) 0.0081(0.0386) 0.1234***(0.0209)
Migrant Stock x Non-English -0.0312(0.0246) -0.0172(0.0131) 0.1166***(0.0243) 0.1311***(0.0126)
Zero Migrants 0.3001***(0.0818) 0.5724***(0.0854) 0.3471***(0.0917) 0.1829***(0.0674)
Foreign GDP 0.2354***(0.0736) 1.2291***(0.054) -0.3185***(0.0897) 1.4846***(0.0667)
New Zealand GDP 0.9014(0.7676) -1.7998***(0.4583) 3.0065***(0.712) 2.3324***(0.4301)
World GDP 2.4517***(0.4441) 0.7697***(0.2464) -0.1135(0.4281) -0.5964**(0.2417)
Population -0.7934***(0.1962) 0.8319***(0.1405) -0.1479(0.2356) -0.4967***(0.1261)
Distance -1.7268***(0.1373) -2.188***(0.0423) -2.0216***(0.1266) -0.7577***(0.0385)
Non-English 0.2182*(0.1154) 0.4086***(0.0756) 0.6323***(0.1172) -1.0876***(0.0764)
Average Migrant Stock 0.0172(0.0349) 0.4232***(0.027) 0.411***(0.0392) 0.3218***(0.0205)
Average Foreign GDP 0.5505***(0.0811) -0.3961***(0.0557) 0.76***(0.0954) -0.5905***(0.0675)
Average Population 0.1412(0.1977) -1.1943***(0.1408) -0.0838(0.2373) 0.5715***(0.1271)
1995 Dummy -0.0852(0.1166) 0.3231***(0.0679) 0.0163(0.1069) -0.1452**(0.0579)
Log Likelihood -894.3325 -6036.8280 -947.3310 -5548.5210
Observations 3385 2574 3385 2388
Countries 179 175 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

Appendix (continued)#

Appendix Table 3– Allowing the effect of migrants to vary by income
Variable Exports Imports
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.9564***(0.0517) 0.0717***(0.0171) 0.3235***(0.0408) 0.1397***(0.0239)
Migrant Stock x Low Income -0.5883***(0.0347) 0.0016(0.0069) -0.2716***(0.0227) 0.0181**(0.0087)
Zero Migrants 0.4973***(0.0878) -0.2101***(0.049) 0.2236***(0.0853) -0.088(0.0776)
Foreign GDP 0.6189***(0.0925) 0.9689***(0.0503) -0.2753***(0.0891) 1.4106***(0.0727)
New Zealand GDP 3.0125***(0.8116) 0.5156(0.3539) 3.1525***(0.7185) 1.9707***(0.4788)
World GDP 4.2631***(0.4845) 0.3847*(0.21) -0.3545(0.4159) -0.6016**(0.2816)
Population -3.8089***(0.2547) -0.544***(0.1084) -0.1778(0.2215) -0.6155***(0.1359)
Distance -2.113***(0.154) -2.4532***(0.0357) -1.4124***(0.1157) -1.3265***(0.043)
Non-English -0.2668***(0.0672) 0.2849***(0.0301) 0.7119***(0.0605) -0.2622***(0.0394)
Average Migrant Stock -0.0222(0.035) 0.2693***(0.0176) 0.3074***(0.0381) 0.2535***(0.0245)
Average Foreign GDP -0.3444***(0.0977) -0.0072(0.0526) 0.5773***(0.0954) -0.0995(0.0748)
Average Population 3.6026***(0.2556) 0.2551**(0.1091) 0.1426(0.2238) 0.2488*(0.1372)
1995 Dummy -0.443***(0.1187) 0.1393***(0.0482) 0.0409(0.1097) -0.0381(0.0633)
Log Likelihood -763.5893 -6229.473 -920.6506 -5824.8030
Observations 3385 2721 3385 2406
Countries 179 176 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

Appendix Table 4– Allowing the effect of migrants to vary by income, excluding agriculture and oil
Variable Exports (Excluding Agriculture) Imports (Excluding Oil)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.7837***(0.0495) 0.1483***(0.0242) 0.3929***(0.0411) 0.2635***(0.0193)
Migrant Stock x Low Income -0.4747***(0.0339) -0.1154***(0.0085) -0.3413***(0.022) -0.0523***(0.0077)
Zero Migrants 0.2942***(0.08) 0.3231***(0.0828) 0.2347***(0.0859) 0.0569(0.0666)
Foreign GDP 0.2247***(0.0727) 1.2397***(0.0552) -0.2985***(0.0898) 1.4703***(0.0656)
New Zealand GDP 0.896(0.7662) -1.3902***(0.447) 3.1212***(0.7037) 2.4059***(0.429)
World GDP 2.4603***(0.4416) 0.4234*(0.2414) -0.1401(0.4168) -0.6377***(0.2406)
Population -0.8293***(0.1938) 0.8173***(0.1372) -0.2437(0.229) -0.6032***(0.1217)
Distance -2.5465***(0.1494) -2.7107***(0.0418) -1.4581***(0.1181) -1.1756***(0.0383)
Non-English 0.1198*(0.0617) 0.578***(0.0363) 0.576***(0.0595) -0.3121***(0.0351)
Average Migrant Stock -0.0396(0.0343) 0.3602***(0.0249) 0.3578***(0.0388) 0.3428***(0.02)
Average Foreign GDP 0.2629***(0.0804) -0.4718***(0.0581) 0.3969***(0.0951) -0.7456***(0.0672)
Average Population 0.4773**(0.1961) -1.0675***(0.1387) 0.3527(0.2315) 0.7398***(0.1227)
1995 Dummy -0.0807(0.1167) 0.3384***(0.0644) 0.013(0.1067) -0.1459**(0.0577)
Log Likelihood -887.9186 -6014.4170 -944.252 -5549.555
Observations 3385 2574 3385 2388
Countries 179 175 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

 

 

Appendix (continued)#

 

 

Appendix Table 5– Allowing elasticity to change with the number of migrants, excluding agriculture and oil
Variable Exports (Excluding Agriculture) Imports (Excluding Oil)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.6787***(0.0497) -0.0084(0.0297) 0.3303***(0.0549) 0.5234***(0.0261)
Square of Migrant Stock -0.0594***(0.0049) 0.0097***(0.002) -0.0377***(0.0049) -0.0294***(0.0018)
Zero Migrants 0.7859***(0.1005) 0.3657***(0.0942) 0.6452***(0.1119) 0.6215***(0.0745)
Foreign GDP 0.2326***(0.0725) 1.2161***(0.0544) -0.2947***(0.0889) 1.5916***(0.0672)
New Zealand GDP 0.8668(0.7638) -1.4047***(0.4479) 2.9532***(0.7061) 2.3633***(0.4292)
World GDP 2.4298***(0.4383) 0.4006*(0.2417) 0.0088(0.4247) -0.5227**(0.2405)
Population -0.5959***(0.1963) 0.8446***(0.1359) -0.1637(0.2379) -0.7077***(0.1262)
Distance -2.3857***(0.1441) -1.9993***(0.041) -2.0313***(0.1259) -1.1945***(0.0384)
Non-English 0.1784***(0.0605) 0.354***(0.0366) 0.8423***(0.0604) -0.3685***(0.0351)
Average Migrant Stock 0.1799***(0.0332) 0.4534***(0.0255) 0.4228***(0.0392) 0.3361***(0.021)
Average Foreign GDP 0.5453***(0.0802) -0.4676***(0.0562) 0.8465***(0.095) -0.7066***(0.0679)
Average Population -0.0433(0.1978) -1.1322***(0.1364) -0.1363(0.24) 0.7789***(0.1272)
1995 Dummy -0.0835(0.1162) 0.334***(0.0645) 0.0205(0.1067) -0.1569***(0.0581)
Log Likelihood -889.9513 -6016.3110 -945.2068 -5543.5900
Observations 3385 2574 3385 2388
Countries 179 175 179 171

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

– The effect of migration on tourism exports for the period 1996 to 2001

Appendix Table 6– The effect of migration on tourism exports for the period 1996 to 2001
Variable Tourism Exports (Model One) Tourism Exports (Model Two)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.3024***(0.0565) 0.2229***(0.0158) 0.3435***(0.1166) -0.2884***(0.02)
Square of Migrant Stock --- --- -0.0071(0.0164) 0.0685***(0.0012)
Zero Migrants -0.0294(0.2153) 0.3413***(0.0658) 0.0308(0.2621) -0.7807***(0.0686)
Foreign GDP 0.4538***(0.1568) 0.8192***(0.0401) 0.4586***(0.158) 0.8798***(0.036)
New Zealand GDP -4.0545(3.6708) 3.0583***(0.7369) -3.9886(3.694) 2.1228***(0.6642)
World GDP 3.0966(3.3804) -1.1532*(0.6882) 3.0365(3.4028) -0.6598(0.6183)
Population 0.488(0.5068) -1.9789***(0.1229) 0.4987(0.5072) -1.7778***(0.114)
Distance -2.5969***(0.2473) -2.0869***(0.0242) -2.5882***(0.2481) -1.4652***(0.0223)
Non-English 0.2092**(0.1045) -0.0669***(0.02) 0.2145**(0.1047) -0.3331***(0.0187)
Average Migrant Stock 0.1198**(0.0568) 0.1244***(0.0156) 0.1285**(0.0583) -0.0474***(0.0141)
Average Foreign GDP -0.0039(0.1679) -0.041(0.0415) -0.0102(0.1696) -0.13***(0.0373)
Average Population -0.6898(0.5223) 1.6046***(0.1254) -0.6987(0.5227) 1.4699***(0.1164)
Log Likelihood -268.3399 -1240.788 -268.3183 -1229.783
Observations 1052 851 1052 851
Countries 178 172 178 172

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are short term visitor flows to New Zealand during any given year.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

 

 

Appendix (continued)#

 

 

Appendix Table 7 – The effect of including a real exchange rate variable in our benchmark export equation
Variable Exports (Model One) Exports (Model Two)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock 0.4269***(0.0761) 0.0871***(0.0213) 0.4206***(0.0781) 0.0975***(0.0225)
Zero Migrants 1.1483***(0.2011) -0.5003***(0.0644) 1.1714***(0.2036) -0.4805***(0.0627)
Foreign GDP 2.0985***(0.2175) 1.1976***(0.0723) 2.0441***(0.2211) 1.2134***(0.0757)
New Zealand GDP -0.7151(1.2615) 0.4716(0.4482) -0.4889(1.3037) 0.2399(0.4506)
World GDP 3.1171***(0.8422) -0.2805(0.2609) 2.745***(0.9304) -0.0895(0.2676)
Population -0.5536(0.4688) -0.9707***(0.1398) -0.69(0.4814) -0.6579***(0.1419)
Distance -2.8711***(0.3392) -3.2196***(0.0436) -2.87***(0.3408) -3.2148***(0.0447)
Non-English -0.5685***(0.1358) -1.287***(0.039) -0.5397***(0.1348) -0.4936***(0.037)
Real Exchange Rate --- --- -0.2476***(0.0956) 0.2947***(0.0275)
Average Migrant Stock -0.1883***(0.0718) -0.0032(0.0222) -0.1869**(0.0734) 0.0139(0.0237)
Average Foreign GDP -0.9222***(0.209) 0.0826(0.0756) -0.8845***(0.2123) -0.0322(0.0785)
Average Population -0.3696(0.4594) 0.6523***(0.1387) -0.206(0.4707) 0.1946(0.1411)
1995 Dummy -0.3966*(0.2075) 0.252***(0.063) -0.3552*(0.2074) 0.2219***(0.0621)
Log Likelihood -257.0576 -3278.7860 -256.5664 -3271.179
Observations 1726 1540 1726 1540
Countries 90 90 90 90

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.

Appendix Table 8 – The effect of including a real exchange rate variable in our benchmark import equation
Variable Imports (Model One) Imports (Model Two)
  Selection Trade Selection Trade
Migrant Stock -0.185***(0.0702) 0.4348***(0.0321) -0.1931***(0.0714) 0.4518***(0.0331)
Zero Migrants -0.4762***(0.1499) -0.4628***(0.0984) -0.479***(0.1497) -0.4465***(0.1022)
Foreign GDP 0.736***(0.2129) 1.4569***(0.1004) 0.7237***(0.2119) 1.4099***(0.1038)
New Zealand GDP 3.6932***(1.1558) 2.1829***(0.6132) 3.9276***(1.1739) 2.1513***(0.6378)
World GDP -2.6928***(0.7932) -0.6653*(0.3398) -2.883***(0.8074) -0.4997(0.3527)
Population -0.0702(0.4991) -1.5854***(0.1657) -0.2419(0.5341) -1.532***(0.1998)
Distance -0.3891**(0.1748) -1.7056***(0.0535) -0.374**(0.1754) -1.8542***(0.0532)
Language 1.462***(0.1031) 0.0367(0.0508) 1.4576***(0.1035) -0.3919***(0.0493)
Real Exchange Rate --- --- -0.1637(0.1569) 0.1055***(0.0356)
Average Migrant Stock 0.6995***(0.0726) -0.0241(0.0335) 0.7145***(0.0737) -0.1471***(0.0342)
Average Foreign GDP -0.4656**(0.2191) -0.0822(0.102) -0.4626**(0.2187) -0.1131(0.1053)
Average Population -0.0988(0.5014) 1.1249***(0.166) 0.082(0.5406) 1.2223***(0.2018)
1995 Dummy 0.0572(0.1623) 0.0171(0.0849) 0.0694(0.1624) 0.0026(0.0862)
Log Likelihood -376.3119 -3211.8510 -376.1041 -3210.7710
Observations 1726 1378 1726 1378
Countries 90 89 90 89

Notes – For definitions of the variables refer to Table 3.  A constant term and country specific effects are included in all regressions.  Dependent variables are in 1995 New Zealand dollars.  Three stars (***) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, two stars (**) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level.