Formats and related files
Abstract#
Understanding productivity performance is important to informing policy advice on how to improve productivity and therefore New Zealand's overall economic performance. Given data limitations inherent in international productivity comparisons, this paper is not intended to inform policy in isolation but forms an important element of a wide and expanding body of evidence on the performance of the New Zealand economy. Previous international productivity comparisons involving New Zealand have been confined to the aggregate economy or to broadly-defined sectors such as manufacturing. This paper reports on a New Zealand-UK comparison which distinguishes 21 different ‘market sectors’ (ie, excluding public administration, education, health, property services and some personal, social and community services). It confirms the prevailing consensus that, in aggregate, New Zealand market sectors compare unfavourably with the UK on average labour productivity (ALP) - and by implication compare even more unfavourably with other countries such as the US. However, beneath this overall story there is considerable sectoral variation. While some NZ sectors out-perform the UK on ALP and/or multi-factor productivity (MFP), there is a large group of sectors which fall short of the UK on both productivity measures. Most of these low-productivity sectors are relatively low in physical capital-intensity compared to the UK. Overall, roughly a quarter of the New Zealand-UK gap in ALP for aggregate market sectors in 2002 was attributable to differences in employment structure such as the relatively high shares of New Zealand employment in comparatively low value added sectors such as agriculture. The remaining three quarters of the ALP gap were accounted for by within-sector productivity differences.
Acknowledgements#
This project has been financially supported by NZ Treasury which is not however responsible for any views expressed in this paper. We are particularly grateful to Gerard Ypma at the Groningen Growth and Development Centre for preparation of purchasing power parity exchange rates and to Joel Cook, Antony Ede and Jodi York at Statistics NZ for preparation of customised data series. We would also like to thank Carl Bakker, Max Dupuy, Brian Easton, Kevin Fox, Melody Guy, Dean Hyslop and Dean Parham for comments on earlier drafts of this paper and our colleagues Mary O’Mahony, Kate Robinson and Brigid O’Leary for advice and support during the project. Responsibility for any errors is ours alone.
Disclaimer#
The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this Working Paper are strictly those of the author(s). They do not necessarily reflect the views of the New Zealand Treasury. The Treasury takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the information contained in these working papers. The paper is presented not as policy, but with a view to inform and stimulate wider debate.
1 Introduction#
Productivity performance is now central to economic policy debates in New Zealand due to public concern about the country’s decline relative to many other advanced industrial countries in measures of living standards such as average Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per head of population. For example, IMF (2002) noted that New Zealand’s real GDP growth since 1985 had been below the OECD average and that the gap between New Zealand and Australia in real GDP per capita widened throughout this period. Schreyer (2006, Table 1) shows that low GDP per capita in New Zealand is not attributable to lower levels of labour utilisation (as measured by average hours worked per capita) compared to Australia, or indeed several other countries. By contrast, there is a clear link between relatively low levels of GDP per capita and weak performance on labour productivity (average output per hour worked).
IMF (2002) estimate that in 1999 average labour productivity (ALP) in market sectors in New Zealand was only 73% of the Australian level, down from 82% in 1988. Around three quarters of the Australian-New Zealand ALP gap is attributed to a relatively low level of physical capital per unit of labour input in New Zealand with the remainder attributed to lower multi-factor productivity (MFP) which captures, among other things, differences in the efficiency with which existing capital and labour resources are utilised. Hall and Scobie (2005) confirm the gap in capital intensity between New Zealand and Australia which is associated with a much lower cost of labour relative to capital in New Zealand compared to Australia. At the aggregate economy level Schreyer (2006) estimates that New Zealand ALP in 2002 was roughly 76% of the Australian level, 69% of the UK level and 61% of the US level. He also finds average physical capital-intensity and MFP in New Zealand to be markedly lower than in Australia, the UK or the US.
To date most productivity levels comparisons involving New Zealand have been confined to the aggregate economy or to broadly-defined sectors such as manufacturing. In part this has reflected gaps in sector-level data and the difficulties involved in the choice of appropriate exchange rates for converting sectoral outputs in different countries to a common currency. However, highly aggregated comparisons potentially conceal marked disparities between different sectors in New Zealand in relative productivity performance. Hence, there is a strong motivation to carry out cross-country productivity comparisons at a more disaggregated sectoral level than hitherto.
In this paper we present the results of a New Zealand-UK comparison which distinguishes 21 different sectors within the ‘market economy’.[1] To achieve this we have drawn on a number of different data sources in the two countries, including customised data series prepared by Statistics New Zealand and a new set of sector-level purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rate estimates for New Zealand prepared by the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) at the University of Groningen in the Netherlands. Inevitably, our findings come with a number of caveats due to the inherent difficulties of comparing ‘like with like’ across countries. Therefore, the decisions we have taken in order to maximise data comparability across New Zealand and the UK are explained at some length in the main text and in an Appendix on Sources and Methods.
The paper is ordered as follows: Section 2 outlines our methodology, with particular reference to the choice of PPPs. Section 3 presents our benchmark estimates of comparative levels of ALP and MFP for total market sectors in New Zealand and the UK. Section 4 then presents our estimates of relative ALP levels at detailed sector level over the ten years from 1995-2004. Section 5 reports on cross-country differences in production inputs, focussing on capital stocks, capital-labour ratios and labour quality. Section 6 compares estimated MFP levels at sector level in the two countries over the same ten-year period and reports on the estimated contributions of physical and human capital inputs to cross-country differences in ALP. It then assesses recent trends in growth rates of output, labour input, ALP and MFP at sector level. Section 7 summarises the main findings of interest. Throughout the study we place New Zealand’s relative productivity performance in wider perspective by drawing on recent comparisons of the UK, US, France and Germany which have been carried out at the National Institute of Economic and Social Research (NIESR).
Notes
- [1]The ‘market economy’ is here defined to exclude public administration, education, health, property services and some personal, social and community services (see Section 3 for further details).
2 Methodology#
2.1 Theoretical specification#
Growth in Average Labour Productivity (ALP) is defined as the growth in average output per unit of labour input (for example, per worker-hour) over a specified period of time. By contrast, growth in another widely cited productivity measure – Multi-Factor Productivity (MFP) – is defined as the increase in output (net of intermediate inputs) that cannot be attributed to increases in the quantity or quality of physical capital and labour, for example, growth in output deriving from more efficient deployment of existing resources.
Thus MFP is evaluated as a residual after taking account of measured growth in other production inputs. As well as capturing improved efficiency in resource utilisation, it also includes the effects of ‘disembodied’ technical change, that is, technical improvements and innovations which are not embodied in measured capital inputs. Other variables which may be picked up by a MFP measure include economies of scale, capacity utilisation and measurement errors of different kinds.
Letting Y denote nominal value added and L labour input, average labour productivity (ALP)for industry i and country k at time t is defined as:
(1)
Relative labour productivity levels comparing countries k and j can be derived as the ratio of labour productivity for both countries, but with value added Y denominated in a common currency. To achieve the latter it is necessary to multiply value added in j by the ratio of its prices to those in the numeraire country k. Thus relative labour productivity levels are given by:
(2)
ALP growth between periods t and t-1 can be calculated from equation (1) except that each country’s domestic price indexes are employed to deflate nominal values. Combining levels with growth rates allows calculation of relative labour productivity at each point in time.
In order to estimate relative levels of multi-factor productivity (MFP) in different countries, we use growth accounting methods which have been employed extensively in international comparisons of productivity growth rates and levels, e.g. in Jorgenson, Gollop and Fraumeni (1987), O’Mahony (1999) and O’Mahony and van Ark (2003). The theoretical underpinning for this approach is the neoclassical growth model, with underlying assumptions that all markets are competitive and that all factors in the production process are paid their marginal products, the sum of which exhausts all returns from pursuing those activities. In addition the use of value added to measure output involves the assumption that material input is separable from other inputs in the production function.
Under these assumptions MFP levels in country J relative to country K in industry i can be calculated using the Törnqvist discrete approximation to the Divisia index, given by:
(3) In(MFPij,k)= In(RYij,k) - αij,k In(RLij,k)In(RKij,k)
where RYJ,K denotes value added in country J relative to country K (with nominal output converted to a common currency), RL is relative labour input, RK is relative capital stocks, and αJ,K is the share of labour in value added averaged over the two countries. Assuming constant returns to scale, the weight on capital is one minus labour’s share of value added.
Analogously, comparing periods t and t-1, again letting Y denote real output, L labour and K capital, and dropping the country subscript, the Törnqvist MFP growth index is given by: ;
(4) In(MFPi,t) - In MFPi,t-1) = (In Yi,t - In Yi,t-1) - ϖil,k(In Li,t-1) - (1 - ϖil)(In Ki,t - In Ki,t-1)
whereϖil, is the share of labour in the value of output, averaged across periods t and t-1.
In addition, changes in the quality of labour input in each industry may be estimated by extending the growth accounting method to distinguish labour by skill type with each type weighted by its wage bill share. Hence, assuming there are l types of labour hours (L), a change in aggregate labour input can be estimated as:
(5)
with weights equal to the share of each labour type in the total wage bill. A measure of labour quality change in each industry can be derived from the difference between dlabour as defined above and the growth in total worker-hours.
2.2 Data sources and measurement issues#
For this study we make use of National Accounts data on gross output, value added, and labour inputs in each country while using production censuses such as the Annual Business Inquiry in the UK to obtain more disaggregated information as and when required. Throughout we use National Accounts aggregates as control totals since international conventions are employed in National Accounts measurement and so these data are usually the most internationally comparable.
In order to construct capital stocks series, we make use of capital investment data provided by the UK Office for National Statistics (ONS) and Statistics New Zealand (SNZ). For cross-country comparisons these estimates require assumptions on common sector-specific depreciation rates across the countries in question. Therefore our capital stocks estimates for both New Zealand and the UK are based on US depreciation rates, with assets divided into structures, vehicles, computers, other plant and machinery and intangibles (principally software).[2] Letting c denote types of capital, with I denoting investment and d the (geometric) depreciation rate, capital stocks are measured as:
(6)
The growth in aggregate capital is then calculated in an analogous manner to aggregate labour as in equation (5) above, with weights equal to the share of each asset type in the total value of capital. This provides a basis for benchmark estimates of relative capital stocks in each country with PPPs for investment goods employed to convert capital to a common currency. Further details are set out in Section 5.1.
The primary sources for data on employment and wages by skill type (proxied by qualifications category) are the Labour Force Survey (LFS) for the UK and the NZ Income Survey and NZ Census of Population and Dwellings. Previous research comparing labour force skills across countries has tended to divide the labour force into three or four categories of formal qualifications and then attempted to match those categories across countries (see, for example, O’Mahony, 1999). This method is sensitive to the allocation of qualifications to the various categories which is fraught with difficulty due to the differences in education and training institutions and formal qualifications systems in each country. Hence in this study our approach is to benchmark on the highest qualifications category (First/Bachelor degree and above) where comparability across countries is at its strongest and then use the ratios of mean wages in other qualification groups relative to mean graduate wages within each country to derive a country-specific measure of labour quality. This approach is explained in detail in Section 5.2.
For conversion of nominal value added to a common currency for sector-level productivity comparisons, one potential source of purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rate estimates is the ‘expenditure PPPs’ produced by Eurostat and OECD. However, these are designed to capture cross-country differences in standards of living rather than productivity differences and so the goods and services priced frequently include imported goods and do not include prices for intermediate products and services. An alternative source is unit value ratios (UVRs) calculated as sales of products divided by quantities produced. UVRs - which may be described as ‘output PPPs’ -- are clearly closer to the required producer price concept for sector-level comparisons. However, in practice, due to limited availability of quantity data in some sectors, as well as difficulties in matching products, it is necessary to employ a combination of output PPPs and expenditure PPPs, with the latter adjusted for relative trade and transportation margins and for taxes. For this project we make use of a new set of sector-level purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rate estimates for New Zealand prepared by the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) which comprise a mix of UVRs and adjusted expenditure PPPs.[3] Further details of the GGDC methodology are set out in Appendix Section A2.
3 Productivity, capital-intensity and labour quality in the aggregate market economy#
Before going on to present sector-level productivity estimates, we first present an overview of our findings at aggregate market economy level. ‘Market sectors’ are here defined to include agriculture, forestry and fishing; mining and quarrying; manufacturing; electricity, gas and water supply; construction; wholesale, retail and other distribution activities; hotels and restaurants; transport, storage and communications; financial services; business services (excluding property services); and cultural and recreational services. They equate to what Statistics NZ (2006a) defines as the New Zealand ‘measured sector’ plus Business Services (ANZSIC Division LC). The excluded sectors are those which are dominated by public ownership (eg, public administration, education and health) and/or where no satisfactory measures of output exist in one or both countries (eg, property services, including residential buildings, and some personal, social and community services). A full list of market sectors with matching industrial classifications is shown in Table 1.
UK SIC | ANZSIC | Sector name |
---|---|---|
01-05 | AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing |
10-14 | BA | Mining |
15-16 | CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing |
17-19 | CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing |
20-21 | CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing |
22 | CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media |
23-25 | CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing |
26 | CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing |
27-28 | CG | Metal product manufacturing |
29-35 | CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing (mechanical, electrical, electronic and instrument engineering; vehicle manufacturing) |
36 | CI | Furniture and other manufacturing |
40-41 | DA | Electricity, gas and water supply |
45 | EA | Construction |
51 | FA | Wholesale trade |
50, 52 | GA | Retail trade |
55 | HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars |
60-63 | IA | Transport and storage |
64 | JA | Communication services |
65-67 | KA | Finance and insurance |
71-74 | LC | Business services |
92-93 | PA | Cultural and recreational services |
Using a market sectors PPP exchange rate derived by aggregating up from sector-level estimates (see Section 4.1), we estimate that in our chosen benchmark year (2002), average value added per hour worked in New Zealand market sectors was some 77% of the UK market sectors level, down from 82% in 1995 (Table 2). This differential may be compared against the estimate in Schreyer (2006, Table 1) that New Zealand GDP per hour worked in 2002 was roughly 69% of the UK level. The 8 pp difference between these two results is not large considering that (1) non-market sectors are excluded in our case and (2) our results are based on sector-specific PPP exchange rates rather than on the GDP PPP exchange rates used by Schreyer (2006).
Estimated contributions to NZ/UK gap in ALP: proportions | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Average labour productivity (UK=100) | Multi-factor productivity (UK=100) | Relative capital-intensity | Relative labour quality | Relative MFP | |
1995 | 82 | 86 | 0.52 | -0.27 | 0.75 |
1996 | 80 | 85 | 0.49 | -0.24 | 0.75 |
1997 | 80 | 84 | 0.44 | -0.25 | 0.82 |
1998 | 77 | 81 | 0.38 | -0.20 | 0.82 |
1999 | 74 | 79 | 0.36 | -0.16 | 0.79 |
2000 | 75 | 81 | 0.40 | -0.14 | 0.74 |
2001 | 77 | 85 | 0.49 | -0.18 | 0.68 |
2002 | 77 | 87 | 0.57 | -0.14 | 0.57 |
2003 | 76 | 87 | 0.53 | -0.09 | 0.56 |
2004 | 75 | 87 | 0.53 | -0.04 | 0.52 |
Notes: All estimates are for calendar years in contrast to the typical presentation of National Accounts data for years ending March 31st in New Zealand (see Appendix Section A1 for details of the assumptions made in order to convert March year data to a calendar year basis).
2002 benchmark estimates of average value added per hour worked have been extrapolated back to 1995 and forward to 2004 on the basis of movements in constant price value added and labour inputs in each country. See Appendix Section A2 for a discussion of the advantages and disadvantages of this use of ‘constant PPPs’ as compared to an alternative ‘current PPPs’ approach. For details of the aggregate market sectors PPP exchange rate in 2002 see Table 4 below.
As will be shown in Section 5 below, average physical capital per hour worked in New Zealand market sectors was some 69% of the UK level in 2002 while average labour quality, on the measure used in this report, was an estimated 7% above the UK level.[4] ;When account is taken of these New Zealand-UK differences in relative capital-intensity and labour quality, then the average MFP level in New Zealand market sectors in 2002 was some 87% of UK levels, much the same as in 1995 (Table 2, Column 2). Between 2002-04 our estimates show a small relative decline in the New Zealand position on the ALP measure but not on MFP.
Using growth accounting methods described in Section 2.1, we can decompose the New Zealand-UK differences in relative ALP levels into three components:
- The proportion explained by differences in relative physical capital-intensity.
- The proportion explained by differences in relative labour quality.
- The residual MFP component.
Columns 3-5 in Table 2 show that higher average physical capital per hour worked in the UK accounted for roughly 57% of the New Zealand-UK gap in ALP in 2002 and was partly offset by the higher average level of labour quality in New Zealand (-14%). The residual MFP contribution to the ALP gap was thus 57%. Trends over time in the relative capital-intensity and labour quality measures are shown in Figure 1 alongside the trends in relative ALP and MFP. While New Zealand MFP increased relative to the UK between 1999-2002, it is still no higher than in 1995 and in recent years appears to have been largely offset by declines in relative capital-intensity and a narrowing of the NZ lead over the UK in labour quality.
In comparing New Zealand with the UK it should be borne in mind that the UK is by no means a productivity leader among advanced industrial nations. Recent NIESR estimates for 2002 show that the UK lagged some 40 pp behind the US in terms of ALP, 32 pp behind France and 22 pp behind Germany. As shown in Figure 2, these gaps in ALP were associated in large part with lower physical capital-intensity in the UK compared to the other three countries and to a much lesser extent with gaps in relative labour quality.
- Figure 1 - Relative ALP, MFP, physical capital per hour worked and labour quality, aggregate market sectors, New Zealand/UK, 1995-2004
-
- Notes: For details of calculations underlying the relative capital-intensity and labour quality measures, see Sections 5.1 and 5.2 respectively.
Another perspective on recent trends in productivity growth in New Zealand and the UK is provided by decomposing average annual rates of ALP growth in aggregate market sectors, firstly, between growth in output and hours worked; and secondly, between the respective contributions of growth in physical capital, labour quality and MFP. Over the whole period from 1995-2004, average annual growth in output in the two countries was much the same. However, New Zealand experienced faster growth in labour inputs over this period. Although this is a positive outcome in terms of job creation, the net outcome was slower growth in ALP (averaging 2% per annum in New Zealand compared to 3% in the UK (Table 3). Average annual growth rates in MFP were the same in both countries over this period but the UK also benefited from faster growth of physical capital-intensity and a positive (albeit small) impact of growth in measured labour quality which narrowed the NZ lead on this measure between 1998-2004. The bulk of the growth in labour inputs in New Zealand occurred during the period 2000-04 when output growth was considerably faster than in the UK but productivity growth in the UK was similar to New Zealand due to a reduction in annual hours worked and continued growth in physical capital.
- Total market sectors in the 4-country study includes some real estate activities (part of SIC 70) and social, community and personal services (UK SIC 90-91) which are not included in the definition of market sectors in the present study. In total these sectors account for just under 4% of total market sectors employment in the UK in the 4-country study.
- Average annual hours worked per employee in the 4-country study were derived from GGDC (2005) for all four countries, including the UK. However, for the present UK-New Zealand comparison new estimates of UK hours worked have been derived from Labour Force Survey data in order to achieve greater comparability with New Zealand hours data. This makes little difference to estimates of relative ALP at total market sectors level.
- Relative capital per hour worked in the four-country study is based on measures of three different types of capital asset: structures, plant and machinery and vehicles. For the present study we distinguish five different capital assets: structures, computers, other plant and machinery, vehicles and intangibles (principally software).
- Figure 2 - Relative ALP, physical capital-intensity and labour quality in the UK, US, France and Germany, aggregate market sectors, 2002 (Index numbers: UK=100)
-
- Notes: Derived from Mason, O’Leary, O’Mahony and Robinson (2006).
- Some differences between this 4-country study and the present study need to be noted:
Average annual rates of growth (%): | Contributions to ALP growth (pp): | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Output | Hours worked | Average labour productivity | Physical capital | Labour quality | MFP | |
1995-2004 | ||||||
UK | 3.4 | 0.5 | 3.0 | 1.1 | 0.3 | 1.5 |
NZ | 3.6 | 1.6 | 2.0 | 0.6 | -0.1 | 1.5 |
1995-2000 | ||||||
UK | 4.3 | 1.1 | 3.2 | 1.1 | 0.3 | 1.7 |
NZ | 2.2 | 0.8 | 1.4 | 0.8 | 0.1 | 0.5 |
2000-2004 | ||||||
UK | 2.4 | -0.3 | 2.6 | 1.0 | 0.3 | 1.2 |
NZ | 5.3 | 2.6 | 2.7 | 0.4 | -0.4 | 2.7 |
Note: All estimates are for calendar years in contrast to the typical presentation of National Accounts data for years ending March 31st in New Zealand. Hence the estimated growth rates for New Zealand are not directly comparable with those produced by Statistics New Zealand(see Appendix Section A1 for details of the assumptions made in order to convert March year data to a calendar year basis).
Notes
- [4]Note that a number of caveats attach to this estimate of relative labour quality; see Section 5.2.
4 Comparative productivity at sector level#
In order to carry out benchmark comparisons of ALP levels in 2002, nominal value added in each country was first converted to US dollar values using sector-specific PPP exchange rates (Table 4). For measures of labour inputs, total annual hours worked in the UK at sector level were estimated by multiplying total employment (employees plus self-employed) by estimates of average annual hours worked per person derived from the UK Labour Force Survey. For New Zealand estimates of total annual hours worked were derived from SNZ estimates of paid hours for all employed persons, described in SNZ (2006b), with an upward adjustment to an hours worked basis using NZ Household Labour Force Survey data (see Appendix Section A1.2 for further details).
The results in Table 5 show that the UK lead over New Zealand in total market sectors applies to both aggregate manufacturing and aggregate market services. In some manufacturing sectors the UK lead even exceeds 50 pp (for example, textiles and clothing, printing and publishing and petroleum and chemicals) and the New Zealand deficit is also substantial in large service sectors such as retail. However, the results also highlight areas of relatively strong performance in New Zealand which have hitherto been masked by comparisons at aggregate economy level.
Five sectors stand out where our estimates point to a New Zealand lead of 5 pp or more over the UK:
- Food, drink and tobacco
- Accommodation, restaurants and bars
- Communication services
- Finance and insurance
- Cultural and recreational services
In addition in metal product manufacturing New Zealand ALP is estimated to be just ahead of the UK level at 102. These six sectors account for roughly 30% of total output in New Zealand market sectors and 22% of total hours worked (Table 5, Columns 2 and 4).
UK SIC | ANZSIC | Sector | NZ$ per US$ |
Type of PPP | UK £ per US$ |
Type of PPP |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
01-05 | AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 2.65 | UVR | 0.67 | UVR |
10-14 | BA | Mining | 2.27 | UVR | 1.34 | UVR |
15-16 | CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 1.33 | E-PPP | 0.68 | E-PPP |
17-19 | CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 2.54 | E-PPP | 0.83 | UVR/E-PPP |
20-21 | CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 2.48 | E-PPP | 0.69 | UVR |
22 | CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 2.15 | E-PPP | 0.51 | E-PPP |
23-25 | CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 2.34 | E-PPP | 0.55 | UVR |
26 | CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 1.64 | E-PPP | 0.47 | UVR |
27-28 | CG | Metal product manufacturing | 1.34 | E-PPP | 0.64 | UVR/E-PPP |
29-35 | CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 1.99 | E-PPP | 0.89 | UVR/E-PPP |
36 | CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 1.73 | E-PPP | 0.69 | UVR/E-PPP |
40-41 | DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 2.37 | UVR/E-PPP | 0.68 | UVR/E-PPP |
45 | EA | Construction | 1.35 | E-PPP | 0.69 | E-PPP |
51 | FA | Wholesale trade | 2.56 | UVR/E-PPP | 0.75 | UVR/E-PPP |
50, 52 | GA | Retail trade | 2.03 | UVR/E-PPP | 0.79 | UVR/E-PPP |
55 | HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 1.26 | E-PPP | 1.12 | E-PPP |
60-63 | IA | Transport and storage | 1.98 | UVR | 0.83 | UVR |
64 | JA | Communication services | 2.33 | UVR | 0.61 | UVR/E-PPP |
65-67 | KA | Finance and insurance | 1.26 | E-PPP | 0.60 | E-PPP |
71-74 | LC | Business services | 1.29 | E-PPP | 0.68 | E-PPP |
92-93 | PA | Cultural and recreational services | 1.23 | E-PPP | 0.83 | E-PPP |
01-67; 71-74; 92-93 | Total market sectors | 1.75 | 0.73 | |||
15-37 | Manufacturing | 1.68 | 0.67 | |||
50-67; 71-74; 92-93 | Market services | 1.68 | 0.72 | |||
01-14; 40-45 | Other sectors | 2.05 | 0.77 | |||
GDP PPP exchange rate | 1.47 | 0.61 | ||||
Average market exchange rate | 2.16 | 0.67 |
Notes: UK PPP exchange rates are taken from Mason et al (2006). New Zealand PPP exchange rates are GGDC estimates for 1997 updated to 2002 on the basis of producer price changes at sector level between 1997-2002 in New Zealand and the US, with additional adjustments for electricity, gas and water, wholesale and retail based on updated 1999 OECD expenditure PPPs in order to make the New Zealand PPPs for those industries more comparable with UK PPPs. GDP PPPs and market exchange rates are taken from OECD (2005, Table 1.12). Estimated PPPs for total market sectors are those implied by summing value added in US$ for each sector, as derived by using sector-specific PPPs, and then dividing these US$ totals by the sum of value added in New Zealand and UK domestic currencies. A similar approach derives estimated PPPs for aggregate manufacturing and market services. See Appendix Section A2 for further details.
% shares of total gross value added in aggregate market sectors | % shares of total hours worked in aggregate market sectors | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
UK SIC | ANZSIC | Sector | NZ/UK Average labour productivity (UK=100) | NZ | UK | NZ | UK |
01-05 | AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing * | 78 | 10.4 | 1.3 | 12.2 | 2.6 |
10-14 | BA | Mining | 82 | 2.0 | 3.2 | 0.3 | 0.4 |
15-16 | CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 105 | 7.4 | 3.1 | 5.2 | 2.4 |
17-19 | CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 48 | 1.0 | 0.8 | 1.7 | 1.1 |
20-21 | CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 59 | 2.5 | 0.9 | 2.3 | 1.0 |
22 | CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 36 | 1.7 | 2.3 | 1.7 | 1.8 |
23-25 | CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 38 | 2.3 | 3.8 | 1.8 | 2.5 |
26 | CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 56 | 0.8 | 0.8 | 0.7 | 0.7 |
27-28 | CG | Metal product manufacturing | 102 | 2.3 | 2.2 | 2.5 | 2.6 |
29-35 | CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 61 | 3.0 | 6.5 | 3.8 | 6.0 |
36 | CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 46 | 0.6 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 1.2 |
40-41 | DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 90 | 3.0 | 2.3 | 0.5 | 0.7 |
45 | EA | Construction | 70 | 5.8 | 8.0 | 10.0 | 10.0 |
51 | FA | Wholesale trade | 86 | 11.7 | 6.0 | 8.0 | 6.4 |
50, 52 | GA | Retail trade | 55 | 7.8 | 10.6 | 15.1 | 15.2 |
55 | HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 113 | 2.3 | 4.2 | 5.6 | 7.0 |
60-63 | IA | Transport and storage | 88 | 6.7 | 6.5 | 5.8 | 6.2 |
64 | JA | Communication services | 115 | 6.0 | 4.1 | 2.0 | 3.1 |
65-67 | KA | Finance and insurance | 112 | 9.0 | 9.9 | 3.8 | 5.2 |
71-74 | LC | Business services | 89 | 10.9 | 18.7 | 12.6 | 19.3 |
92-93 | PA | Cultural and recreational services | 128 | 3.0 | 3.8 | 3.3 | 4.2 |
01-67; 71-74; 92-93 | Total market sectors | 77 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 | |
15-37 | Manufacturing | 70 | 22 | 21 | 21 | 19 | |
50-67; 71-74; 92-93 | Market services | 87 | 57 | 64 | 56 | 67 | |
01-14; 40-45 | Other sectors | 62 | 21 | 15 | 23 | 14 | |
*Agriculture, forestry and fishing (Alternative estimate - see text below) | 101 |
Note: All estimates are for calendar years in contrast to the typical presentation of National Accounts data for years ending March 31st in New Zealand (see Appendix Section A1 for further details).
In many respects these are plausible findings. For example, we might expect New Zealand to be more specialised than the UK in food processing, and the relative strength of metal products within New Zealand manufacturing may partly reflect the disproportionate influence of the large aluminium producer Comalco. In Section 5 below we assess the contributions of relative physical capital-intensity and labour quality to the New Zealand leads in these six sectors. However, before doing so we need to discuss the uncertainties underlying estimates of this kind and assess the sensitivity of some results to alternative reasonable assumptions regarding such variables as PPP exchange rates and labour inputs.
With regard to New Zealand PPPs, there was a shortage of matching revenue and quantity data for some manufacturing sectors which prevented the calculation of unit value ratios (UVRs) even though UVRs were available for those sectors in the UK (Table 4). The sectors affected were wood and paper products, petroleum and chemicals and non-metallic mineral products. Hence for these sectors we developed a sensitivity test based on the ratios of UVRs to expenditure PPPs for these same sectors in Australia, using estimates provided by GGDC. These ratios were then applied to the New Zealand expenditure PPPs used in our New Zealand-UK comparison. In two cases this led to a sharp increase in the estimated New Zealand ALP level relative to the UK - up from 59 to 75 in wood and paper products and 38 to 52 in petroleum and chemicals. However, in non-metallic mineral products relative ALP barely changed (down from 56 to 55). We conclude that in two of these three sectors the estimated size of the New Zealand ALP gap relative to the UK is highly sensitive to the type of PPP exchange rate which is used; however, the existence of a relatively large productivity gap in these sectors is not in doubt.
One industry where New Zealand-UK comparisons are particularly difficult to carry out is agriculture. Since previous comparisons have found ALP in New Zealand agriculture to be among the highest in world terms (Prasada Rao, 1993), it comes as a surprise to find that estimated ALP in New Zealand agriculture, forestry and fishing in 2002 is only 78% of the UK level (compared to 115% only five years earlier; see Table 6, Row 1). [5] The estimated agriculture PPP for New Zealand in 2002 seems high - NZ$2.65 to US$1.00 - but this represents an appropriate update from the much lower PPP that GGDC estimated for 1997 (NZ$1.56) since agricultural prices in New Zealand rose rapidly between 1997-2002 whereas in the US they declined for many products. [6] The main factor explaining the seeming rapid improvement in UK labour productivity compared to New Zealand turns out to be a reported decline in UK agricultural employment of 23% between 1997-2002 while real output rose by 7%.[7] In New Zealand the equivalent changes over the same period were a 7% increase in labour input and a 4% increase in real output.[8]
However, further investigation suggests that the UK National Accounts employment total for agriculture may be a considerable under-estimate since annual surveys carried out by the UK Department for the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA) report total employment roughly 26% higher than the National Accounts total for 2002, and show a slower rate of decline in employment (down approximately 15% between 1997-2002).[9] In view of these disparities in official information on UK agricultural employment, we report alternative estimates of relative ALP for this sector using DEFRA employment data which show New Zealand ahead at 133% of the UK level in 1997, then declining to near-parity in 2002 (Appendix Table A1, bottom row). In view of the data uncertainties, both sets of estimates for this sector must be regarded as unsatisfactory.[10] (For purely illustrative purposes all estimates relating to agriculture in subsequent tables are based on UK National Accounts employment totals).
Apart from these problems specific to agriculture, our estimates are potentially sensitive to the choice of benchmark year due to different business cycle conditions in each country and underlying volatility in some sectoral data series. Figure 3 shows that in manufacturing New Zealand has a consistent lead on ALP in food processing from 1995-2003 while the UK retains a consistent lead in seven other manufacturing sectors over the same period. In service sectors New Zealand is ahead throughout 1995-2004 in accommodation and restaurants and cultural and recreational services while the UK lead remains intact in wholesale and retail. The UK is also well ahead over this period in utilities and construction, although the gap narrows in utilities from 1999 onwards.
This leaves three sectors - mining, transport and business services - where New Zealand recorded higher ALP than the UK in the mid-late 1990s but has subsequently fallen behind. Conversely, the NZ lead in communication services in our benchmark year (2002) has only developed in very recent years.
In nearly all the sectors where New Zealand consistently lags behind the UK on ALP, the implication of the recent UK-US-French-German comparative study is that New Zealand is even further behind the other four countries (see Appendix Table A4). For reasons pointed out in the notes to Table A4, as well as the different levels of sectoral disaggregation that are involved and problems of transitivity, caution is strongly advised in drawing inferences from reading across the two sets of results. However, there do appear to be some sectors where New Zealand may enjoy a productivity lead over other countries besides the UK, for example, in food processing and some branches of financial services relative to France and Germany. There do not appear to be any sectors where New Zealand is ahead of the US on ALP at this level of disaggregation.
- Figure 3 - Average labour productivity in market sectors, New Zealand and UK, 1995-97, 1998-2000, 2001-2003 (Index numbers: UK=100, Three-year averages)
Notes: Estimates are shown as three-year averages on a calendar year basis. 2002 benchmark estimates of average value added per hour worked have been extrapolated back to 1995 and forward to 2004 on the basis of movements in constant price value added and labour inputs in each country. See Appendix Table A1 for full time series. The second sector listed “Agriculture, forestry and fishing (Defra emp)” shows how New Zealand compares against the UK in this sector when alternative UK employment figures provided by the Department of Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (Defra) are used; see main text for details.
Notes#
- [5]According to Prasada Rao (1993), New Zealand also ranked highly in terms of agricultural output per unit of land if land is defined as total arable land plus permanent crop land. However, if land is defined to include permanent meadows and pastures as well as arable land, then New Zealand output per hectare compares less favourably with many European countries because of the much more intensive use of land in European farming.
- [6]These different price movements largely reflect weak New Zealand exchange rates against the US dollar for much of this period combined with the very different composition of agricultural output in New Zealand and the US. For example, New Zealand producer prices per tonne of sheep meat rose by 41% between 1997-2002 while US producer prices per tonne of maize fell by 5.2%. Note that NZ sheep and goat meat production was 5.6 times higher than the US in 2002 while New Zealand maize production was less than 1% of US output (Source: http://faostat.fao.org/. These data illustrate the difficulties of identifying comparable products for which to gather price information in the two countries.
- [7]ONS, Blue Book, 2006, Tables 2.4 and 2.5.
- [8]See Appendix Section A1.2 for details of New Zealand data sources.
- [9]Source:NIESR estimates based on data from the June Agricultural and Horticultural Survey, DEFRA [available at: http://www.defra.gov.uk/esg/work_htm/publications/cs/farmstats_web/2_SURVEY_DATA_SEARCH/HISTORICAL_DATASETS/HISTORICAL_DATASETS/historical_datasets.htm
- [10]Some of the problems in estimating UK agricultural employment may partly be due to the extensive use of poorly-recorded migrant labour.
5 Relative physical capital-intensity and labour quality at sector level#
5.1 Capital stocks and capital-labour ratios#
In Section 2.2 above we outlined the perpetual inventory method of estimating capital stocks that cumulates constant price investments and deducts the value of depreciated assets. If we assume that depreciation rates are geometric, this has the advantage that they are easy to implement, in particular, if long time series of investments are not available but it is possible to make reasonable estimates of starting stocks. The disadvantage of this assumption is that assets are depreciated rapidly at the beginning of the asset’s life but depreciation then tails off subsequently. This assumption is more reasonable for assets where technological change is rapid than it is for assets such as structures.
In order to derive comparable estimates of net capital stocks in New Zealand and the UK, common sector-specific depreciation rates were applied to National Accounts investment data in each country. This approach follows O’Mahony (1993, 1999) who has shown that cross-country comparisons of official capital stocks figures are sensitive to differences in measurement techniques used by national statistical offices. Five asset types were distinguished: structures (non-residential buildings and other construction), computers, other plant and machinery, vehicles and intangibles (defined in the UK as consisting of patents, mineral exploration, artistic originals and the value of computer software). Investment data in national currencies were converted to US$ using OECD PPPs for investment goods by asset type. Finally, starting values for capital stocks were required in order to implement the perpetual inventory formula. In the UK starting values were set in 1948 by raising investment for that year by a factor equal to 0.5* (1/dj) where dj denotes the depreciation rate for asset type j. [11] In New Zealand the starting year for applying this formula ranged from 1859 for buildings to 1964 for computers.
Across market sectors as a whole, average physical capital per hour worked in New Zealand is estimated at 69% of the UK level in 2002, down from 78% in 1995. This is broadly consistent with estimates at aggregate economy level reported by Schreyer (2006). As shown in Figure 4, in 14 of the 21 sectors New Zealand capital-intensity was relatively low compared to the UK throughout the 1995-2004 period: agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining, food processing, printing and publishing, petroleum and chemicals, non-metallic mineral products, machinery and equipment, furniture and other manufacturing, retail, hotels and catering, transport and storage, finance and insurance, business services and cultural and recreational services.
However, in four sectors New Zealand recorded higher capital-intensity than the UK for at least part of this period: textiles and clothing, metal products, electricity, gas and water supply and wholesale trade. And in another three sectors relative physical capital per hour worked has been consistently higher in New Zealand throughout the period: communication services, construction and wood and paper products.
Given that the UK has on average invested much less in physical capital assets in recent decades than countries such as the US, France and Germany, it is important not to overstate the significance of New Zealand being more capital-intensive than the UK in certain sectors. Reading across from comparisons of the UK with the US, France and Germany (see Appendix Table A5) suggests that physical capital-intensity in communication services may be comparable with that in the US and France but physical capital per hour worked in construction and wood and paper products is still much lower in New Zealand than in the other three countries. Nonetheless, it is useful to be able to take account of sectoral variation in relative capital-intensity in New Zealand when seeking to evaluate the factors contributing to relatively weak overall productivity performance.
- Figure 4 - Average physical capital per hour worked in market sectors, New Zealand/ UK, 1995-97, 1998-2000, 2001-03 (Index numbers: UK=1.00, Three-year averages)
-
- Notes: Estimates are shown as three-year averages on a calendar year basis. Estimated productive capital stocks were initially supplied for New Zealand in constant price 1995-96 NZ$ and for the UK in 2002 constant price £ sterling. Both these series were converted to constant price 1999 US$ using 1999 OECD PPPs for non-ICT investment goods by asset type along with deflators based on movements in investment goods producer price indices in the UK, US and New Zealand. For computers and software (assumed to be representative of intangibles), US ICT capital stock deflators were used, obtained from http://www.csls.ca/data/ict.asp. Full time series shown in Appendix Table A2.
Notes
- [11]This is based on the idea that about 50% of an asset is depreciated within half its average life length. This kind of assumption is reasonable if the starting value is a long time before the capital stocks are employed in analysis (in this study 1995).
Disaggregation of productive capital stocks by asset-type shows that, across market sectors as a whole, New Zealand makes less intensive use of each different type of capital and - with the exception of vehicles in the late 1990s - this has been the case throughout 1995-2004 (Table 6). The less intensive use of computers and intangibles in New Zealand suggests that, if the capital stock indices were weighted by their shares in total user costs to yield a measure of capital services per hour worked, the New Zealand-UK gap on this measure would be even greater than on the capital stocks measure. [12]
Structures | Non-ICT equipment | Vehicles | Computers | Intangibles | Total capital | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1995 | 0.78 | 0.70 | 1.01 | 0.56 | 0.71 | 0.78 |
1996 | 0.76 | 0.71 | 1.01 | 0.58 | 0.68 | 0.77 |
1997 | 0.77 | 0.74 | 1.05 | 0.65 | 0.63 | 0.79 |
1998 | 0.76 | 0.74 | 1.01 | 0.59 | 0.58 | 0.77 |
1999 | 0.73 | 0.72 | 0.96 | 0.56 | 0.57 | 0.74 |
2000 | 0.73 | 0.72 | 0.94 | 0.50 | 0.56 | 0.73 |
2001 | 0.72 | 0.73 | 0.90 | 0.48 | 0.54 | 0.72 |
2002 | 0.69 | 0.72 | 0.84 | 0.46 | 0.52 | 0.69 |
2003 | 0.68 | 0.72 | 0.85 | 0.48 | 0.53 | 0.69 |
2004 | 0.66 | 0.71 | 0.86 | 0.54 | 0.53 | 0.68 |
Again, disaggregation by sector for a recent year highlights some interesting variation beneath the aggregate results (Table 7). Four sectors in New Zealand do make more intensive use of computers than their UK counterparts: agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining, construction and cultural and recreational services. The two primary sectors also make more intensive use of intangibles (but in mining the disparity is so great as to suggest that there are marked differences between the two countries in the way that investments in intangibles in this industry are recorded). There are several sectors where New Zealand has accumulated (proportionately) more investments in structures and/or vehicles than in the UK and rather fewer where NZ is ahead in terms of investments in non-ICT machinery and equipment. The exceptions to this observation are wood and paper product manufacturing, transport services, communication services and cultural and recreational services which do make more intensive use of non-ICT equipment.
Structures | Non-ICT equipment | Vehicles | Computers | Intangibles | Total capital | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 0.27 | 0.26 | 1.80 | 11.57 | 3.13 | 0.33 |
BA | Mining | 0.31 | 0.38 | 1.58 | 2.06 | 21.38 | 0.41 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 0.88 | 0.88 | 0.68 | 0.46 | 0.30 | 0.85 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 0.76 | 0.50 | 0.78 | 0.30 | 0.41 | 0.58 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 1.23 | 1.51 | 0.87 | 0.33 | 0.97 | 1.37 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 0.95 | 0.75 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.66 | 0.80 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 0.70 | 0.60 | 1.20 | 0.44 | 0.33 | 0.63 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 1.23 | 0.52 | 4.37 | 0.54 | 0.24 | 0.75 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 1.23 | 0.83 | 1.62 | 0.61 | 0.58 | 0.96 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 0.53 | 0.33 | 2.02 | 0.28 | 0.48 | 0.41 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 1.14 | 0.46 | 0.80 | 0.47 | 0.37 | 0.65 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 2.45 | 0.32 | 0.74 | 0.76 | 0.08 | 1.10 |
EA | Construction | 1.50 | 0.98 | 2.18 | 1.50 | 0.56 | 1.37 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 0.86 | 0.68 | 1.03 | 0.63 | 0.47 | 0.75 |
GA | Retail trade | 0.23 | 0.58 | 0.96 | 0.52 | 0.47 | 0.37 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 0.45 | 0.84 | 1.73 | 0.29 | 0.17 | 0.54 |
IA | Transport and storage | 0.50 | 1.01 | 0.79 | 0.24 | 0.50 | 0.67 |
JA | Communication services | 4.42 | 1.77 | 0.84 | 0.63 | 2.85 | 2.29 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 0.29 | 0.71 | 1.37 | 0.57 | 1.05 | 0.56 |
LC | Business services | 0.66 | 0.63 | 0.36 | 0.54 | 0.90 | 0.59 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 0.36 | 1.70 | 0.56 | 1.66 | 0.38 | 0.58 |
Total market sectors | 0.69 | 0.72 | 0.84 | 0.46 | 0.52 | 0.69 |
Notes
- [12]This is because investment in short-lived ICT products which are subject to rapid price declines can typically only be justified by their higher productivity (hence higher shares of total user costs) relative to capital assets with longer service lives.
5.2 Relative labour quality#
In order to explore the impact of labour quality differences on relative productivity performance, estimates of relative skill levels have been derived on the basis of educational attainments and mean wage levels analysed by qualifications category in the UK and New Zealand for the period 1995 to 2004. This is an experimental approach building on current work at NIESR which seeks to develop labour quality measures that are more closely related to worker productivity than standard measures of educational inputs such as average years of schooling.
Using data from the UK Labour Force Survey, we group UK qualifications into the following four categories in order to obtain estimates of mean wages by qualifications category at sector level:
- First / Bachelor degrees and above
- Other NVQ4 plus NVQ3 or equivalent, eg A levels (academic qualifications for 17-18 year old school-leavers and technician- and craft-level vocational qualifications (NVQ = National Vocational Qualifications)
- NVQ2 and NVQ1 or equivalent (relatively low-level qualifications associated with semi-skilled employment)
- No qualifications
For New Zealand we use NZ Income Survey data to group New Zealand qualifications into three categories in order to obtain similar estimates of mean wages by qualifications category:
- Bachelor degrees and above
- Post-secondary school qualifications below Bachelor level (for example, Trade certificates, Advanced trade certificates, NZ certificates or diplomas and local polytech diplomas)
- No post-school qualifications
Since there is no obvious way to match qualification groups below graduate level between the two countries, we follow the approach outlined in Mason, et al (2006) of benchmarking on graduate-level qualifications (where comparability across countries is at its strongest), and then using ratios of mean wages in non-graduate categories to mean graduate wages in each country as indicators of labour quality differences between the respective categories.
In more detail, we create an indicator of relative quality-adjusted labour input Lq in industry i for two countries j and k as follows, denoting the benchmark category of degree holders as h and the remainder of the workforce as o:
(7)
where
(8)
and similarly for k,
and Sih(j,k) is the average share of labour compensation paid to group h in industry i across the two countries; Sio(j,k)is the average of (1- Sih) across the two countries; Lih represents graduate-level labour input (hours worked) and L*io represents quality-adjusted non-graduate labour input where hours are weighted by the relative wage of non-graduate skill groups (wp) to that of graduates (wh). In this way, all non-graduate hours worked are calculated as ‘effective units of labour’ with a graduate base.
This is a relatively general model which has the advantage of allowing the relative marginal products across different qualification categories to vary across countries (as they may very well do in practice).
Two obvious underlying assumptions in this approach are (1) a broad similarity between countries in graduate-level productivity; and (2) that mean wage differentials between qualification categories reflect differences in the average productivity levels of persons classified to each qualification category. With regard to assumption (1), we argue that graduates are notably more mobile across national borders than those in other qualification groups and there is widespread acceptance by employers in New Zealand and the UK from overseas. Assumption (2) is consistent with the standard growth accounting assumption of perfectly competitive markets (in which a firm hires an additional hour of labour up to the point where that person’s marginal productivity equals his/her marginal cost). However, it makes no allowance for cross-country differences in labour market institutions such as minimum wage legislation and the role of trade unions in wage-setting. In spite of this shortcoming, we hope that the resulting measure of relative labour quality goes some way towards capturing variations in relative marginal products across different sub-graduate qualification categories in each country.
New Zealand-UK differences in the distribution of qualifications and in wage differentials in 2002 are shown in Table 8. Three things stand out in particular: (1) the higher graduate share of employment in the UK, 15% compared to 11% in New Zealand; (2) the smaller (38%) proportion of the New Zealand workforce with post-secondary school qualifications compared to 72% in the UK; (3) the relatively narrow wage differentials attached to holding degree-level qualifications rather than sub-degree qualifications or no post-school qualifications in New Zealand. This latter point could reflect relatively low returns to university study as compared to the UK or it could reflect relatively high returns to post-school work experience and (uncertified) training or a combination of both factors. Some part of the relatively high returns to ‘No post-school qualifications’ may also be due to the fact that this category includes academic qualifications attained by 17-18 year old school-leavers when they are the highest qualification attained by the individuals concerned whereas equivalent UK school-leaving qualifications such as A levels are included in the NVQ3 category in the UK.
Using this information on employment shares by qualification group and qualification-related wage differentials, we derive a measure of relative labour quality which shows New Zealand to be approximately 7% higher than the UK across total market sectors in 2002 but on a declining trend from a 10% lead in 1998 to only 2% in 2004 (Table 9). This progressive decline in the estimated labour quality differential reflects a continued reduction in the employment share of workers lacking formal qualifications in the UK coupled with a decline towards the end of the period in sub-graduate pay differentials in New Zealand (see Appendix Section A3).
Employment shares (%) | Ratio of mean wages to mean graduate wages | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
UK | NZ | UK | NZ | |
Graduates | 15 | 11 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
NVQ 3-4 (UK) | 37 | 0.66 | ||
Post-secondary school qualifications below Bachelor level (NZ) | 38 | 0.72 | ||
NVQ 1-2 (UK) | 35 | 0.53 | ||
No post-school qualifications (NZ) | 51 | 0.59 | ||
No qualifications (UK) | 12 | 0.46 | ||
TOTAL | 100 | 100 |
Sources: Derived from UK Labour Force Survey and the NZ Income Survey. See notes to Table 11 for further details.
However, a caveat needs to be entered about the estimates of qualification shares of employment in New Zealand which have been derived from the NZ Income Survey (NZIS). Data from the NZ Census of Population and Dwellings for 2001 point to the following, rather different employment shares in aggregate market sectors: Graduates 11%, Post-school qualifications below Bachelor level 22%; No post-school qualifications 67%. If these Census employment shares were applied to the NZIS wage data, then the estimated New Zealand lead in average labour quality in 2002 would be approximately halved and by 2004 it would disappear.
On the advice of Statistics NZ (discussed further in Appendix Section A3), we regard the NZIS data as more reliable but clearly the discrepancy between the two sources adds to the uncertainty attached to our estimates of labour quality. In addition to the data uncertainties, it is also of concern that mean annual pay for New Zealand graduates in 2002, converted to US dollars at GDP PPP exchange rates, was roughly a third below mean graduate pay in the UK. Clearly, a detailed analysis of graduate salaries in the two countries is beyond the scope of this report; however, if New Zealand graduates are typically low paid by international standards, this could contribute to relatively narrow pay differentials between graduates and non-graduates in New Zealand, thus artificially raising New Zealand labour quality according to the measure we have adopted. We therefore continue to use this measure in this report with some reservations.
Table 9 suggests considerable variation between sectors in measured labour quality with the New Zealand skills index ranging from 95% of the UK level in mining up to 14-15% above the UK level in textiles and clothing, wholesale, transport and communications. Since Mason et al (2006) found the UK to be lagging behind the US, France and Germany by 2-5 pp on a similar measure of relative labour quality, we conclude that, on this measure at least, average labour quality in New Zealand compares favourably with the other three countries (see Appendix Table A6).
In summary, the measured labour quality gap between New Zealand and the UK represents the net outcome of two main phenomena noted above, that is, the higher employment shares of persons holding certified qualifications in the UK and the relatively high returns to sub-graduate qualifications and uncertified experience and training in New Zealand. In spite of our reservations, our labour quality measure does seem to capture potentially interesting contrasts in skills formation between the two countries which are worthy of further investigation.
Table 9 - Relative labour quality worked in market sectors, New Zealand/UK, 1995-2004 (Index numbers: UK=1.00)
SIC | Sector | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SIC | Sector | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 |
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 1.18 | 1.18 | 1.18 | 1.18 | 1.14 | 1.14 | 1.15 | 1.11 | 1.08 | 1.07 |
BA | Mining | 1.05 | 1.06 | 1.03 | 1.04 | 1.00 | 1.00 | 0.97 | 0.95 | 0.90 | 0.93 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 1.20 | 1.18 | 1.21 | 1.18 | 1.07 | 1.07 | 1.09 | 1.11 | 1.14 | 1.13 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 1.24 | 1.21 | 1.26 | 1.25 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.15 | 1.16 | 1.14 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 1.21 | 1.18 | 1.22 | 1.18 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.09 | 1.13 | 1.15 | 1.14 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.01 | 1.01 | 1.00 | 1.04 | 1.08 | 1.07 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 1.14 | 1.13 | 1.16 | 1.13 | 1.02 | 1.02 | 1.02 | 1.04 | 1.08 | 1.07 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 1.18 | 1.18 | 1.21 | 1.20 | 1.08 | 1.08 | 1.10 | 1.11 | 1.15 | 1.14 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 1.19 | 1.17 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.07 | 1.07 | 1.06 | 1.09 | 1.14 | 1.12 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 1.16 | 1.14 | 1.17 | 1.15 | 1.04 | 1.04 | 1.03 | 1.06 | 1.11 | 1.10 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 1.19 | 1.19 | 1.22 | 1.18 | 1.08 | 1.08 | 1.07 | 1.13 | 1.15 | 1.14 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.10 | 1.11 | 1.11 | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.07 | 1.06 |
EA | Construction | 1.11 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.11 | 1.09 | 1.06 | 1.03 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.14 | 1.14 | 1.13 | 1.13 | 1.15 | 1.14 | 1.11 | 1.06 |
GA | Retail trade | 1.14 | 1.15 | 1.14 | 1.14 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.16 | 1.13 | 1.09 | 1.06 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 1.18 | 1.17 | 1.16 | 1.16 | 1.17 | 1.17 | 1.17 | 1.15 | 1.11 | 1.07 |
IA | Transport and storage | 1.14 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.16 | 1.14 | 1.11 | 1.08 |
JA | Communication services | 1.16 | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.14 | 1.14 | 1.14 | 1.15 | 1.14 | 1.11 | 1.08 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 1.09 | 1.10 | 1.08 | 1.06 | 1.07 | 1.07 | 1.09 | 1.07 | 1.04 | 1.02 |
LC | Business services | 1.08 | 1.07 | 1.05 | 1.05 | 1.04 | 1.04 | 1.06 | 1.05 | 1.03 | 1.03 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 1.11 | 1.12 | 1.12 | 1.12 | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.11 | 1.10 | 1.07 | 1.05 |
Total market sectors | 1.10 | 1.10 | 1.11 | 1.10 | 1.08 | 1.08 | 1.08 | 1.07 | 1.04 | 1.02 |
Notes: All estimates are for calendar years. UK estimates are derived from Labour Force Surveys 1995-2004. NZ estimates of employment shares by qualification group at sector level are derived from NZ Income Survey data at a relatively high level of sectoral aggregation with more disaggregated sectoral estimates based on NZ Census data for 1996 and 2001. Since NZIS data were only available for 1997-2004, the estimated series was then backdated to 1995 on the basis of rates of change between 1997-99. Estimates of qualification-related wage differentials for full-time workers were derived for aggregate manufacturing and aggregate market services in each country and then used to weight employment shares by qualification group in relevant sectors; for agriculture, mining, utilities and construction, employment shares were weighted by the wage differentials for aggregate market sectors. See Appendix Section A3 for further details.
6 Explaining New Zealand-UK differences in productivity levels and growth rates at sector level#
6.1 Relative ALP and MFP levels#
We now go on to assess the extent to which the relative importance to productivity performance of physical capital, labour quality and MFP varies between sectors in New Zealand and the UK. Table 10 shows relative levels of MFP at sector level along with a decomposition of the contributions made by differences in physical capital, labour quality and MFP to relative ALP performance.
Estimated contributions to gap in ALP: (proportions) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SIC | Sector | ALP (UK=100) |
MFP (UK=100) |
Relative capital-intensity | Relative labour quality | Relative MFP |
SIC | Sector | ALP (UK=100) |
MFP (UK=100) |
Relative capital-intensity | Relative labour quality | Relative MFP |
Estimated contributions to gap in ALP: (proportions) | ||||||
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 78 | 138 | 3.05 | -0.31 | -1.73 |
BA | Mining | 82 | 180 | 5.45 | 0.08 | -4.53 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco mfg | 105 | 107 | -1.53 | 1.21 | 1.32 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 48 | 47 | 0.10 | -0.11 | 1.01 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 59 | 49 | -0.14 | -0.10 | 1.24 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 36 | 38 | 0.04 | -0.02 | 0.98 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 38 | 44 | 0.12 | -0.02 | 0.90 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product mfg | 56 | 58 | 0.13 | -0.10 | 0.97 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 102 | 96 | -0.59 | 4.10 | -2.51 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 61 | 74 | 0.42 | -0.09 | 0.67 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 46 | 48 | 0.11 | -0.08 | 0.97 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 90 | 82 | -0.66 | -0.23 | 1.89 |
EA | Construction | 70 | 60 | -0.19 | -0.13 | 1.32 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 86 | 91 | 0.82 | -0.52 | 0.70 |
GA | Retail trade | 55 | 70 | 0.48 | -0.13 | 0.66 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants & bars | 113 | 120 | -1.56 | 1.00 | 1.55 |
IA | Transport and storage | 88 | 89 | 0.88 | -0.73 | 0.85 |
JA | Communication services | 115 | 74 | 2.38 | 0.37 | -1.75 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 112 | 150 | -3.43 | 0.37 | 4.06 |
LC | Business services | 89 | 106 | 1.82 | -0.29 | -0.53 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 128 | 145 | -0.96 | 0.33 | 1.63 |
Total market sectors | 77 | 87 | 0.57 | -0.14 | 0.57 |
The UK is ahead of New Zealand on MFP in 14 of the 21 sectors. The seven sectors where New Zealand is ahead comprise four where ALP is also above the UK level and three more where New Zealand ALP is lower but the New Zealand sectors apparently make more efficient use of existing resources than their UK counterparts (agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining and business services). In these sectors the UK lead on ALP is almost wholly attributable to their advantages in physical capital-intensity with MFP making a negative contribution.
In the majority of other sectors where the UK is ahead on ALP, the positive contribution from MFP outweighs that from physical capital and more than offsets the effects of higher measured labour quality in New Zealand. The same is true of nearly all sectors where New Zealand is ahead on ALP, such as food processing, metal products, hotels and catering, finance and insurance and cultural and recreational services. The exception is communication services where New Zealand is ahead of the UK on ALP and this is largely due to higher physical capital-intensity with MFP making a negative contribution.
Figure 5 shows that the pattern of advantage in relative MFP levels identified in 2002 has prevailed in most sectors throughout the 1995-2004 period. The only real exception to this is metal products where New Zealand was behind the UK on MFP during the late 1990s but has evidently gained ground since 2000.
6.2 Comparative growth rates in ALP and TFP#
As noted in Section 3, UK market sectors as a whole enjoyed faster average annual rates of ALP growth between 1995-2004 than did New Zealand. One way to explore the drivers of ALP growth rates is to compare growth rates in output with those in labour input at sector level across countries. Another is to compare the respective contributions of growth rates in physical capital, labour quality and MFP.
- Figure 5 - Relative multi-factor productivity (MFP) levels in market sectors, New Zealand/UK, 1995-97, 1998-2000, 2002-04 (Index numbers: UK=100, Three-year averages)
-
- Notes: Estimates are shown as three-year averages on a calendar year basis. Full time series shown in Appendix Table A6.
In general the slow rate of growth in UK labour input between 1995-2004 (which we identified in Section 3) was due to reductions in employment numbers in several manufacturing sectors and an overall decline of 3.5% over the period in average annual hours worked per employee.[13] In service sectors positive ALP growth in the UK typically reflected output growing much faster than labour inputs. By contrast, in New Zealand in most sectors output growth was slower and labour input growth was faster than in the UK (Table 11). As a result, there are only five sectors where average annual growth in ALP in New Zealand was above that in the UK: electricity, gas and water (which recorded sharp reductions in total hours worked), communication services and metal products (where output grew much more rapidly than labour input) and finance and insurance and wood products (where there was a slight reduction in labour input over the period).
Turning to an assessment of the respective contributions of physical capital-intensity, labour quality and MFP to average annual growth rates in ALP, Table 12A shows that in the UK growth in MFP exceeded growth in capital-intensity in 13 of the 21 sectors. The main exceptions were mining, electricity, gas and water, construction, wholesale, accommodation and restaurants and business services.
In New Zealand MFP growth also exceeded growth in physical capital in 13 of the 21 sectors. Three sectors even showed a decline in physical capital-intensity over the period: petroleum and chemicals, metal products and transport and storage. The highest rates of MFP growth occurred in communication services, metal products and wholesale trade. Communication services also recorded strong growth in capital-deepening as did electricity, gas and water, wood products and finance and insurance.
UK | New Zealand | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Output | Labour input | ALP | Output | Labour input | ALP | ||
SIC | Sector | Average annual rates of growth (%) | |||||
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 0.1 | -3.4 | 3.5 | 1.7 | -0.6 | 2.3 |
BA | Mining | 2.4 | -1.7 | 4.1 | 0.9 | -2.2 | 3.1 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 1.5 | -0.7 | 2.2 | 2.2 | 1.5 | 0.8 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | -7.0 | -10.4 | 3.4 | -0.9 | -3.5 | 2.6 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 1.0 | -2.8 | 3.7 | 2.8 | -0.2 | 3.1 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 2.0 | -0.8 | 2.8 | -0.3 | -1.2 | 0.9 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 0.0 | -1.6 | 1.5 | -0.1 | -0.3 | 0.2 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | -0.4 | -2.6 | 2.2 | 2.8 | 1.3 | 1.4 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | -1.3 | -3.5 | 2.2 | 3.8 | 1.2 | 2.6 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 1.5 | -2.6 | 4.1 | 2.6 | -0.2 | 2.8 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 2.2 | -0.5 | 2.7 | 0.7 | -0.6 | 1.3 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 2.5 | -1.7 | 4.2 | 0.6 | -6.1 | 6.6 |
EA | Construction | 2.4 | 1.0 | 1.4 | 5.6 | 4.7 | 0.8 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 2.9 | -0.2 | 3.1 | 4.0 | 1.0 | 3.1 |
GA | Retail trade | 4.0 | 0.6 | 3.4 | 3.6 | 1.4 | 2.2 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 3.5 | 1.5 | 2.0 | 2.6 | 3.0 | -0.4 |
IA | Transport and storage | 4.6 | 1.0 | 3.6 | 3.3 | 1.6 | 1.7 |
JA | Communication services | 5.7 | 1.1 | 4.6 | 9.4 | 0.2 | 9.2 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 4.4 | 0.6 | 3.8 | 4.5 | -0.3 | 4.8 |
LC | Business services | 6.1 | 3.3 | 2.8 | 4.9 | 5.4 | -0.5 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 3.9 | 2.8 | 1.1 | 5.1 | 5.4 | -0.3 |
Total market sectors | 3.4 | 0.5 | 3.0 | 3.6 | 1.6 | 2.0 |
Physical capital-intensity | Labour quality | MFP | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UK 1995-2004 | Average annual rate of growth in ALP (%) | Contributions to ALP growth (percentage points): | |||
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 3.54 | 1.34 | 0.30 | 1.90 |
BA | Mining | 4.10 | 2.33 | 0.11 | 1.66 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 2.20 | 0.51 | 0.42 | 1.27 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 3.38 | 1.28 | 0.76 | 1.33 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 3.74 | 0.97 | 0.60 | 2.17 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 2.81 | 0.32 | 0.53 | 1.96 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 1.52 | 0.70 | 0.54 | 0.27 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 2.23 | 0.83 | 0.35 | 1.05 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 2.22 | 0.40 | 0.52 | 1.30 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 4.11 | 0.93 | 0.45 | 2.73 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 2.73 | 0.78 | 0.34 | 1.61 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 4.25 | 3.53 | 0.11 | 0.61 |
EA | Construction | 1.43 | 1.81 | 0.17 | -0.55 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 3.13 | 1.74 | 0.29 | 1.10 |
GA | Retail trade | 3.37 | 1.53 | 0.28 | 1.56 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 2.04 | 1.01 | 0.37 | 0.66 |
IA | Transport and storage | 3.59 | 0.59 | 0.15 | 2.85 |
JA | Communication services | 4.58 | 1.20 | 0.42 | 2.96 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 3.84 | 1.51 | 0.39 | 1.93 |
LC | Business services | 2.77 | 3.93 | 0.20 | -1.35 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 1.06 | -0.28 | 0.35 | 0.99 |
Total market sectors | 2.96 | 1.09 | 0.35 | 1.52 |
Physical capital-intensity | Labour quality | MFP | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
New Zealand 1995-2004 | Average annual rate of growth in ALP (%) | Contributions to ALP growth (percentage points): | |||
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 2.29 | 1.69 | -0.22 | 0.81 |
BA | Mining | 3.13 | 2.96 | -0.09 | 0.26 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 0.76 | 0.96 | 0.05 | -0.25 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 2.58 | 0.35 | 0.08 | 2.15 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 3.07 | 1.89 | -0.02 | 1.20 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 0.94 | 0.38 | 0.05 | 0.52 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 0.18 | -0.64 | -0.05 | 0.87 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 1.45 | 0.03 | 0.06 | 1.36 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 2.59 | -0.57 | 0.00 | 3.15 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 2.76 | 0.60 | 0.01 | 2.15 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 1.25 | -0.01 | 0.03 | 1.23 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 6.63 | 7.36 | -0.06 | -0.67 |
EA | Construction | 0.84 | 0.14 | -0.41 | 1.12 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 3.09 | 0.13 | -0.20 | 3.16 |
GA | Retail trade | 2.20 | 0.58 | -0.28 | 1.90 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | -0.37 | 0.68 | -0.40 | -0.66 |
IA | Transport and storage | 1.71 | -0.10 | -0.22 | 2.03 |
JA | Communication services | 9.16 | 4.03 | -0.04 | 5.16 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 4.80 | 1.90 | 0.00 | 2.90 |
LC | Business services | -0.52 | 0.51 | -0.06 | -0.97 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | -0.25 | 0.61 | -0.06 | -0.80 |
Total market sectors | 1.96 | 0.59 | -0.13 | 1.50 |
Notes
- [13]The reduction in average annual hours worked per employee in the UK represents a continuation of a long-term downward trend (Green, 2001). It also represents the net outcome of a relatively high degree of polarisation between long-hours working and part-time employment in the UK compared to other European countries. In 1998 the UK implemented the European Commission’s Working Time Directive which seeks to limit working time but employees are permitted to ‘opt out’ from its regulations in collaboration with their employers. To date the net effects of this Directive on average working time are hard to determine.
7 Summary and assessment#
This study has confirmed the prevailing consensus that, in aggregate, New Zealand market sectors compare unfavourably with the UK on average labour productivity (ALP) - and by implication compare even more unfavourably with other countries such as the US. At total market sectors level the proximate causes for this relatively weak performance on ALP in New Zealand are lower multi-factor productivity (MFP) closely followed by lower physical capital-intensity.
However, beneath this overall story there is considerable sectoral variation. In 2002 there were five sectors in which New Zealand had an estimated lead on ALP of 5 pp or more over the UK: food, drink and tobacco, accommodation, restaurants and bars, communication services, finance and insurance, and cultural and recreational services. In addition, metal products is just ahead of the UK on ALP and there are two sectors -- mining and business services - where New Zealand is behind the UK on ALP but ahead on MFP. This suggests that, although New Zealand firms in these two sectors are on average less capital-intensive than their UK counterparts, many of them make more efficient use of existing resources.
The same is probably true of agriculture as well but due to the uncertainties about UK agricultural employment numbers which we have discussed in this report, we are unable to present a satisfactory New Zealand/UK comparison of ALP in agriculture.
This leaves 12 out of 21 sectors where New Zealand falls short of the UK on both ALP and MFP. These sectors comprise all other manufacturing apart from metal products, electricity, gas and water supply, construction, wholesale, retail and transport services. They represented just under 58% of total hours worked in New Zealand market sectors in 2002. With the exception of wood products, electricity, gas and water and construction, these sectors are all relatively low in physical capital-intensity compared to the UK.
With some reservations we have made use of a measure of relative labour quality which incorporates wage differentials between qualification groups (assumed to proxy productivity differences) as well as differences in the mix of certified qualifications in each country. On this measure New Zealand appears to be ahead of the UK in workforce skills in all sectors except for mining. However, the New Zealand lead has declined since 1998, partly due to increased numbers of UK workers holding certified qualifications and partly due to declining returns to sub-graduate qualifications in New Zealand as compared to degree-level qualifications. In growth accounting terms, the measured advantage in New Zealand skills does serve to partly offset UK advantages in physical-capital intensity and MFP in many sectors. However, the extent of the offset is fairly small, partly because the New Zealand skills lead itself is small and partly because in growth accounting the respective contributions of different production inputs are evaluated separately and thus do not take account of potential complementarities between inputs (such as the contribution of workforce skills to the effective selection and utilisation of capital equipment).
It is worth considering how much of the New Zealand-UK gap in ALP at aggregate market sectors level is due to differences in industrial structure. For example, if New Zealand employment tends to be concentrated in sectors with relatively low absolute levels of ALP (typically less capital-intensive sectors), this might help to explain the overall weakness in ALP relative to the UK. To examine this we follow van Ark et al (2002) in using a shift-share method which decomposes the UK-New Zealand ALP gap into two components with the UK as the base country:
(9)
where LP refers to the average labour productivity level in US$ terms and Si refers to the employment share of industry i in each country. If ALP levels are the same in each country, then the first term on the right-hand side of Equation 9 is zero and the ALP gap is entirely due to differences in employment structure. Conversely, if employment shares are the same in each country, then the second term is zero and the ALP gap is solely attributable to productivity differences between the two countries at sector level.
The results shown in Table 13 suggest that roughly a quarter of the New Zealand-UK gap in ALP for aggregate market sectors is attributable to differences in employment structure such as the relatively high shares of UK employment in sectors with comparatively high value added per employee such as financial and communication services (even though New Zealand is actually ahead on ALP in those two sectors). The other side of this coin is the relatively high concentration of New Zealand employment in comparatively low value added sectors such as agriculture.
However, the remaining three quarters of the ALP gap are accounted for by within-sector productivity differences. To understand the sources of these differences, further research needs to go beyond growth accounting and investigate the factors underlying the proximate causes of the ALP gap which are emphasised in the growth accounting framework, namely, differences in accumulated stocks of physical and human capital and in MFP. For example, how do the cost and incentive structures confronting businesses making investment decisions in New Zealand compare with those in other countries? How well placed are New Zealand businesses to benefit from international knowledge spillovers which might help improve MFP performance through faster innovation and improved efficiency of resource utilisation? What are the effects on incentive structures and innovation performance of New Zealand-specific characteristics such as small population size, low population density and distance from large markets?
ANZSIC (1) | Sector | Mean of NZ and UK ALP levels (US$) | NZ sector shares of total hours worked (%) | UK sector shares of total hours worked (%) | Within-sector productivity effect | Employ-ment structure effect | Total effect |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 13 | 12.2 | 2.6 | 4.0 | -21.1 | -17.1 |
BA | Mining | 100 | 0.3 | 0.4 | 1.2 | 0.9 | 2.2 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 36 | 5.2 | 2.4 | -1.2 | -17.8 | -19.0 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 12 | 1.7 | 1.1 | 2.0 | -1.3 | 0.8 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 20 | 2.3 | 1.0 | 2.9 | -4.6 | -1.6 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 32 | 1.7 | 1.8 | 8.8 | 0.9 | 9.7 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 35 | 1.8 | 2.5 | 11.4 | 4.4 | 15.8 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 34 | 0.7 | 0.7 | 2.3 | 0.1 | 2.4 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 24 | 2.5 | 2.6 | -0.2 | 0.7 | 0.5 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 18 | 3.8 | 6.0 | 7.3 | 6.6 | 13.9 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 16 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 2.4 | -0.2 | 2.2 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 89 | 0.5 | 0.7 | 0.9 | 2.5 | 3.4 |
EA | Construction | 18 | 10.0 | 10.0 | 11.0 | 0.1 | 11.1 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 22 | 8.0 | 6.4 | 3.8 | -6.0 | -2.2 |
GA | Retail trade | 13 | 15.1 | 15.2 | 19.0 | 0.3 | 19.2 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 11 | 5.6 | 7.0 | -1.4 | 2.5 | 1.1 |
IA | Transport and storage | 22 | 5.8 | 6.2 | 3.0 | 1.4 | 4.3 |
JA | Communication services | 43 | 2.0 | 3.1 | -2.6 | 8.7 | 6.1 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 62 | 3.8 | 5.2 | -5.5 | 15.6 | 10.1 |
LC | Business services | 25 | 12.6 | 19.3 | 8.3 | 28.6 | 36.9 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 23 | 3.3 | 4.2 | -3.6 | 3.7 | 0.1 |
Total market sectors | 23 | 100 | 100 | 74.0 | 26.0 | 100 |
References#
Green, F. (2001), It’s been a hard day’s night: the concentration and intensification of work in late twentieth century Britain, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 39:1, March.
Hall, J. and Scobie, G. (2005), Capital shallowness: A problem for New Zealand?, New Zealand Treasury Working Paper, July 2005.
Hyslop, D., Maré, D. and Timmins, J. (2003), Qualifications, employment and the value of human capital, 1986-2001, New Zealand Treasury Working Paper 03/35, December 2003.
Jorgenson, D.W., F.M. Gollop and B. Fraumeni (1987), Productivity and US Economic Growth, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.
Lau, E. and Wallis, G. (2005) International Comparisons of Productivity: Revisions and Interpretation, Economic Trends, No. 617, April (London: Office of National Statistics).
Mason, G., O’Leary, B., O’Mahony, M. and Robinson, K. (2006), Cross-country performance at sector level: the UK compared with the US, France and Germany, Report to Department of Trade and Industry, NIESR, London.
OECD (2002), Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures: 1999 Benchmark Year, OECD, Paris.
OECD (2005), Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures: 2002 Benchmark Year, OECD, Paris.
O’Mahony, M. (1993), Capital stocks and productivity in industrial nations, National Institute Economic Review, 145: 108-117.
O’Mahony, M. (1999), Britain's Productivity Performance 1950-1996, NIESR, London.
O’Mahony, M. and van Ark, B. (eds.) (2003), EU productivity and competitiveness: An industry perspective. Can Europe resume the catching-up process?, European Commission.
Prasada Rao, D. (1993), Intercountry Comparisons of Agricultural Output and Productivity, Rome: Food and Agricultural Organisation (FAO).
Schreyer, P. (2006), International comparisons of levels of capital input and multi-factor productivity, Paper presented at Conference on Determinants of Productivity Growth, Vienna, 15-16 September 2006.
Statistics New Zealand (2006a), Productivity Statistics 1988-2005, March 2006 (www.stats.govt.nz)
Statistics New Zealand (2006b), Productivity Statistics: Sources and Methods, Wellington.
van Ark, B., Stuivenwold, E. and Inklaar, R. (2003), ICOP purchasing power parities for industry comparisons: preliminary estimates, Final Report for Ministry of Economic Affairs, Groningen Growth and Development Centre and The Conference Board.
van Ark, B. and Timmer, M. (2001), PPPs and international productivity comparisons: bottlenecks and new directions, Paper presented at Joint World Bank - OECD Seminar on Purchasing Power Parities, Washington DC, 30 January - 2 February 2001
van Ark, B., Timmer, M. and Inklaar, R. (2002), The Canada-US productivity gap revisited: new ICOP results, Research Memorandum GD-51, Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen.
Appendix - Tables#
ANZ SIC |
Sector | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing* | 88 | 95 | 115 | 106 | 90 | 101 | 95 | 78 | 74 | 78 |
BA | Mining | 90 | 112 | 154 | 153 | 128 | 97 | 97 | 82 | 70 | 83 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 108 | 106 | 115 | 118 | 117 | 114 | 104 | 105 | 103 | 95 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 49 | 56 | 59 | 56 | 54 | 49 | 48 | 48 | 47 | 46 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 63 | 62 | 60 | 59 | 60 | 61 | 57 | 59 | 63 | 60 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 40 | 40 | 39 | 37 | 37 | 36 | 40 | 36 | 37 | 34 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 36 | 37 | 39 | 37 | 37 | 41 | 37 | 38 | 34 | 32 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 59 | 58 | 58 | 57 | 58 | 62 | 55 | 56 | 57 | 55 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 95 | 93 | 95 | 91 | 91 | 100 | 100 | 102 | 107 | 99 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 65 | 62 | 57 | 59 | 60 | 66 | 66 | 61 | 61 | 57 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 49 | 44 | 46 | 50 | 48 | 51 | 45 | 46 | 49 | 43 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 81 | 65 | 63 | 73 | 82 | 97 | 90 | 90 | 83 | 101 |
EA | Construction | 73 | 75 | 77 | 67 | 69 | 71 | 70 | 70 | 73 | 69 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 79 | 74 | 72 | 71 | 79 | 81 | 83 | 86 | 83 | 79 |
GA | Retail trade | 61 | 58 | 60 | 57 | 59 | 59 | 58 | 55 | 55 | 55 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 142 | 141 | 141 | 120 | 117 | 111 | 114 | 113 | 113 | 114 |
IA | Transport and storage | 102 | 99 | 92 | 91 | 93 | 86 | 83 | 88 | 86 | 86 |
JA | Communication services | 80 | 79 | 76 | 77 | 81 | 96 | 105 | 115 | 119 | 120 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 96 | 91 | 98 | 107 | 102 | 106 | 108 | 112 | 111 | 105 |
LC | Business services | 113 | 109 | 97 | 89 | 91 | 88 | 93 | 89 | 90 | 84 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 147 | 148 | 138 | 140 | 138 | 127 | 134 | 128 | 134 | 131 |
Total market sectors | 82 | 80 | 80 | 77 | 74 | 75 | 77 | 77 | 76 | 75 | |
*Agriculture, forestry and fishing (Alternative estimates -see text) | 108 | 117 | 133 | 122 | 107 | 115 | 117 | 101 | 97 | 105 |
Notes: All estimates are for calendar years. 2002 benchmark estimates of average value added per hour worked have been extrapolated back to 1995 and forward to 2004 on the basis of movements in constant price value added and labour inputs in each country.
Appendix Table A2 - Average physical capital per hour worked in market sectors, New Zealand/UK, 1995-2004 (Index numbers: UK=1.00)
ANZ SIC |
Sector | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 0.38 | 0.38 | 0.43 | 0.43 | 0.37 | 0.39 | 0.34 | 0.33 | 0.34 | 0.37 |
BA | Mining | 0.35 | 0.45 | 0.50 | 0.46 | 0.46 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.41 | 0.37 | 0.39 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 0.81 | 0.82 | 0.87 | 0.89 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.83 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 0.87 | 0.96 | 1.07 | 0.96 | 0.80 | 0.73 | 0.65 | 0.58 | 0.53 | 0.49 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 1.31 | 1.31 | 1.35 | 1.47 | 1.37 | 1.23 | 1.35 | 1.37 | 1.40 | 1.30 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 0.72 | 0.74 | 0.74 | 0.80 | 0.87 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.80 | 0.77 | 0.70 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 0.75 | 0.75 | 0.78 | 0.80 | 0.76 | 0.70 | 0.64 | 0.63 | 0.60 | 0.54 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 0.91 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.81 | 0.86 | 0.79 | 0.75 | 0.71 | 0.69 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 1.15 | 1.15 | 1.38 | 1.32 | 1.16 | 1.14 | 1.08 | 0.96 | 0.92 | 0.81 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 0.44 | 0.42 | 0.44 | 0.45 | 0.44 | 0.45 | 0.41 | 0.41 | 0.40 | 0.37 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 0.68 | 0.70 | 0.77 | 0.83 | 0.72 | 0.75 | 0.68 | 0.65 | 0.65 | 0.56 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 0.85 | 0.77 | 0.80 | 0.89 | 1.02 | 1.23 | 1.15 | 1.10 | 1.08 | 1.20 |
EA | Construction | 1.94 | 2.08 | 2.01 | 1.89 | 1.68 | 1.63 | 1.61 | 1.37 | 1.23 | 1.08 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 1.05 | 1.05 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.85 | 0.81 | 0.77 | 0.75 | 0.73 | 0.71 |
GA | Retail trade | 0.46 | 0.45 | 0.45 | 0.42 | 0.42 | 0.41 | 0.40 | 0.37 | 0.37 | 0.36 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 0.67 | 0.60 | 0.66 | 0.58 | 0.57 | 0.53 | 0.53 | 0.54 | 0.60 | 0.64 |
IA | Transport and storage | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.77 | 0.71 | 0.67 | 0.64 | 0.63 |
JA | Communication services | 1.80 | 1.80 | 1.76 | 1.89 | 1.81 | 2.05 | 2.20 | 2.29 | 2.32 | 2.25 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 0.63 | 0.53 | 0.55 | 0.56 | 0.58 | 0.56 | 0.56 | 0.56 | 0.60 | 0.63 |
LC | Business services | 0.91 | 0.88 | 0.83 | 0.71 | 0.65 | 0.61 | 0.63 | 0.59 | 0.61 | 0.60 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 0.47 | 0.48 | 0.47 | 0.46 | 0.52 | 0.52 | 0.58 | 0.58 | 0.59 | 0.59 |
Total market sectors | 0.78 | 0.77 | 0.79 | 0.77 | 0.74 | 0.73 | 0.72 | 0.69 | 0.69 | 0.68 |
Notes: All estimates are for calendar years. Estimated productive capital stocks were initially supplied for New Zealand in constant price 1995-96 NZ$ and for the UK in 2002 constant price £ sterling. Both these series were converted to constant price 1999 US$ using 1999 OECD PPPs for non-ICT investment goods by asset type along with deflators based on movements in investment goods producer price indices in the UK, US and New Zealand. For computers and software (assumed to be representative of intangibles), US ICT capital stock deflators were used, obtained from http://www.csls.ca/data/ict.asp
Appendix Table A3 - Relative multi-factor productivity (MFP) levels in market sectors, New Zealand/UK, 1995-2004 (Index numbers: UK=100)
SIC | Sector name | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AA, AB, AC | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 143 | 153 | 168 | 149 | 140 | 153 | 156 | 138 | 127 | 129 |
BA | Mining | 203 | 210 | 274 | 285 | 244 | 174 | 181 | 180 | 166 | 186 |
CA | Food, beverage and tobacco manufacturing | 109 | 107 | 110 | 114 | 113 | 115 | 107 | 107 | 103 | 96 |
CB | Textile and apparel manufacturing | 43 | 49 | 49 | 47 | 49 | 49 | 49 | 47 | 46 | 46 |
CC | Wood and paper product manufacturing | 51 | 51 | 47 | 46 | 49 | 54 | 48 | 49 | 51 | 50 |
CD | Printing, publishing and recorded media | 44 | 44 | 43 | 40 | 39 | 41 | 45 | 41 | 40 | 39 |
CE | Petroleum, chemical, plastic and rubber product manufacturing | 38 | 38 | 39 | 38 | 38 | 46 | 44 | 44 | 40 | 38 |
CF | Non-metallic mineral product manufacturing | 56 | 56 | 55 | 54 | 55 | 62 | 56 | 58 | 60 | 58 |
CG | Metal product manufacturing | 81 | 80 | 76 | 74 | 79 | 92 | 94 | 96 | 99 | 95 |
CH | Machinery and equipment manufacturing | 75 | 74 | 67 | 67 | 70 | 80 | 82 | 74 | 72 | 69 |
CI | Furniture and other manufacturing | 47 | 42 | 42 | 47 | 46 | 53 | 48 | 48 | 50 | 46 |
DA | Electricity, gas and water supply | 60 | 53 | 50 | 54 | 54 | 56 | 54 | 56 | 53 | 59 |
EA | Construction | 57 | 57 | 59 | 53 | 57 | 58 | 57 | 60 | 66 | 66 |
FA | Wholesale trade | 62 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 68 | 71 | 74 | 78 | 77 | 75 |
GA | Retail trade | 70 | 70 | 71 | 70 | 70 | 71 | 70 | 70 | 74 | 74 |
HA | Accommodation, restaurants and bars | 139 | 145 | 142 | 125 | 123 | 115 | 118 | 120 | 121 | 122 |
IA | Transport and storage | 101 | 100 | 91 | 89 | 93 | 88 | 85 | 93 | 92 | 94 |
JA | Communication services | 54 | 53 | 51 | 51 | 56 | 61 | 66 | 71 | 71 | 75 |
KA | Finance and insurance | 129 | 130 | 137 | 149 | 137 | 142 | 144 | 164 | 161 | 150 |
LC | Business services | 113 | 112 | 103 | 101 | 108 | 107 | 109 | 106 | 108 | 102 |
PA | Cultural and recreational services | 175 | 177 | 168 | 173 | 162 | 148 | 150 | 145 | 156 | 152 |
Total market sectors | 86 | 85 | 84 | 81 | 79 | 81 | 85 | 87 | 87 | 87 |
SIC | Sector | US | France | Germany |
---|---|---|---|---|
SIC | Sector | US | France | Germany |
01-05 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 118 | 71 | 41 |
10-14 | Mining and quarrying | 74 | 47 | 22 |
15-16 | Food, drink and tobacco | 120 | 102 | 72 |
17 | Textiles | 115 | 169 | 113 |
18 | Manufacture of wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur | 190 | 163 | 138 |
19 | Leather and footwear | 141 | 154 | 77 |
20 | Wood and wood products | 144 | 182 | 138 |
21 | Pulp, paper and paper products | 117 | 161 | 131 |
22 | Printing and publishing | 87 | 94 | 83 |
23 | Mineral oil refining, coke and nuclear fuel | 126 | 168 | 172 |
24 | Chemicals | 125 | 157 | 84 |
25 | Rubber and plastics | 110 | 134 | 96 |
26 | Non-metallic mineral products | 82 | 186 | 98 |
27 | Basic metals | 157 | 185 | 160 |
28 | Fabricated metal products | 127 | 139 | 105 |
29 | Mechanical engineering | 138 | 135 | 116 |
30 | Computers and office machinery | 94 | 91 | 109 |
31 | Electrical machinery | 179 | 186 | 124 |
32 | Electronic components and capital goods | 229 | 132 | 108 |
33 | Medical, precision and optical instruments | 149 | 126 | 92 |
34 | Motor vehicles | 229 | 222 | 161 |
35 | Other transport equipment | 134 | 154 | 127 |
36, 37 | Manufacturing nec, Recycling | 104 | 116 | 92 |
40, 41 | Electricity, gas and water supply | 154 | 82 | 53 |
45 | Construction | 129 | 94 | 96 |
50 | Motor vehicle trade and repairs | 119 | 102 | 89 |
51 | Wholesale trade and commission trade | 159 | 109 | 121 |
52 | Retail trade and repair of household goods | 176 | 158 | 107 |
55 | Hotels and catering | 149 | 259 | 77 |
60 | Inland transport | 158 | 120 | 74 |
61 | Water transport | 121 | 85 | 149 |
62 | Air transport | 157 | 138 | 269 |
63 | Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; travel agents | 116 | 133 | 78 |
64 | Post and telecommunications | 146 | 214 | 307 |
65 | Financial services, except insurance and pension funding | 194 | 122 | 91 |
66 | Insurance and pension funding, except compulsory social security | 75 | 43 | 54 |
67 | Activities auxiliary to financial services | 296 | 101 | 117 |
70 | Real estate activities | 171 | 148 | 213 |
71 | Renting of machinery and equipment | 153 | 164 | 505 |
72 | Computer services and related activities | 143 | 152 | 155 |
73 | Research and development | 172 | 119 | 124 |
74 | Other business services | 130 | 132 | 147 |
90, 91, 92, 93 | Other community, social and personal services | 140 | 81 | 172 |
All market sectors | 141 | 132 | 122 |
Notes: Derived from Mason, O’Leary, O’Mahony and Robinson (2006).
Some differences between this 4-country study and the present study need to be noted:
- Total market sectors in the 4-country study includes some real estate activities (part of SIC 70) and social, community and personal services (UK SIC 90-91) which are not included in the definition of market sectors in the present study. These sectors account for just under 4% of total market sectors employment in the UK in the 4-country study.
- Average annual hours worked per employee in the 4-country study were derived from GGDC (2005) for all four countries, including the UK. However, for the present UK-New Zealand comparison new estimates of UK hours worked have been derived from Labour Force Survey data in order to ensure comparability with New Zealand hours data.
SIC | Sector | US/UK | France/UK | Germany/UK |
---|---|---|---|---|
Index numbers (UK=100) | ||||
Index numbers (UK=100) | ||||
SIC | Sector | US/UK | France/UK | Germany/UK |
01-05 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing | 72 | 97 | 94 |
10-14 | Mining and quarrying | 77 | . | 19 |
10-14, 23 | Mining and quarrying; Mineral oil refining, coke and nuclear fuel | . | 18 | . |
15-16 | Food, drink and tobacco | 88 | 137 | 126 |
17 | Textiles | 157 | 200 | 332 |
18 | Manufacture of wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur | 100 | . | 341 |
18-19 | Clothing and leather goods | . | 145 | . |
19 | Leather and footwear | 677 | . | 206 |
20 | Wood and wood products | 148 | . | 236 |
20-21 | Wood and paper products | . | 178 | . |
21 | Pulp, paper and paper products | 179 | . | 239 |
22 | Printing and publishing | 102 | 116 | 178 |
23 | Mineral oil refining, coke and nuclear fuel | 142 | . | 159 |
24 | Chemicals | 136 | . | 174 |
24-25 | Chemicals, rubber and plastics | . | 159 | . |
25 | Rubber and plastics | 85 | . | 97 |
26 | Non-metallic mineral products | 118 | 215 | 226 |
27 | Basic metals | 124 | . | 126 |
27-28 | Basic metals and fabricated metal products | . | 148 | . |
28 | Fabricated metal products | 162 | . | 207 |
29 | Mechanical engineering | 179 | 133 | 166 |
30 | Computers and office machinery | 204 | . | 340 |
30-33 | Computers, electronic and instrument engineering | . | 147 | . |
31 | Electrical machinery | 217 | . | 213 |
32 | Electronic components and capital goods | 137 | . | 143 |
33 | Medical, precision and optical instruments | 218 | . | 180 |
34 | Motor vehicles | 76 | 160 | 152 |
35 | Other transport equipment | 144 | 184 | 185 |
36, 37 | Manufacturing nec, Recycling | 141 | 272 | 285 |
40, 41 | Electricity, gas and water supply | 139 | 92 | 123 |
45 | Construction | 195 | 227 | 260 |
50 | Motor vehicle trade and repairs | 116 | 146 | 191 |
51 | Wholesale trade and commission trade | 154 | 154 | 178 |
52 | Retail trade and repair of household goods | 168 | 167 | 78 |
55 | Hotels and catering | 107 | 185 | 83 |
60 | Inland transport | 134 | . | 241 |
60-63 | Transport services | . | 119 | . |
61 | Water transport | 303 | . | 194 |
62 | Air transport | 90 | . | 109 |
63 | Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; travel agents | 44 | . | 150 |
64 | Post and telecommunications | 208 | 93 | 255 |
65 | Financial services, except insurance and pension funding | 251 | 183 | 213 |
66 | Insurance and pension funding, except compulsory social security | 29 | 97 | 95 |
67 | Activities auxiliary to financial services | 382 | . | . |
70 | Real estate activities | 128 | 44 | . |
71 | Renting of machinery and equipment | 208 | . | 753 |
71, 72, 74, 90 | Rental, computer and other business services | . | 120 | . |
72 | Computer services and related activities | 148 | . | 271 |
73 | Research and development | 119 | 136 | 182 |
74 | Other business services | 159 | . | 645 |
90, 91, 92, 93 | Other community, social and personal services | 60 | 175 | |
01-74; 90-93 | All market sectors | 117 | 128 | 167 |
Notes: Derived from Mason, O’Leary, O’Mahony and Robinson (2006).
Note that relative capital per hour worked in this four-country study is based on measures of only three different types of capital asset: structures, plant and machinery and vehicles. For the present study we distinguish five different capital assets: structures, computers, other plant and machinery, vehicles and intangibles (principally software).
SIC code | Sector | US/UK | France/UK | Germany/UK |
---|---|---|---|---|
SIC code | Sector | US/UK | France/UK | Germany/UK |
01-05 | Agriculture, hunting, Fishing, fish farms, hatcheries etc | 98 | 99 | 109 |
10-14 | Mining, quarrying etc | 92 | 95 | 94 |
15-16 | Food,beverage,tobacco products manufacture | 93 | 90 | 105 |
17 | Textile manufacture | 95 | 109 | 112 |
18 | Clothing,fur manufacture | 95 | 100 | 115 |
19 | Leather,leather goods manufacture | 90 | 97 | 110 |
20 | Wood,straw,cork,wood prods(not furn) | 88 | 92 | 106 |
21 | Pulp,paper,paper prods manufacture | 101 | 103 | 107 |
22 | Printing,publishing,recorded media | 99 | 95 | 98 |
23 | Coke,petrol prods,nuclear fuel man. | 105 | 101 | 102 |
24 | Chemicals,chemical products man. | 103 | 92 | 98 |
25 | Rubber,plastic products manufacture | 99 | 96 | 109 |
26 | Other non-metallic products man. | 95 | 91 | 107 |
28 | Fabric-metal prod (not mach,eqt) man. | 91 | 91 | 104 |
29 | Mach,eqt manufacture | 94 | 97 | 106 |
30 | Office mach,computer manufacture | 112 | 115 | 105 |
31 | Elec mach,eqt manufacture | 109 | 93 | 109 |
32 | Radio,TV,communication eqt man. | 114 | 107 | 108 |
33 | Medical,precision,optical eqt man. | 105 | 97 | 101 |
34 | Motor veh,trailer,etc manufacture | 99 | 93 | 108 |
35 | Other transport eqt manufacture | 102 | 96 | 102 |
36 | Furniture etc manufacture | 96 | 94 | 107 |
40-41 | Electricity, gas and water | 101 | 99 | 103 |
45 | Construction | 93 | 92 | 105 |
50 | Sales of motor vehs,parts,fuel etc | 103 | 99 | 106 |
51 | Wsale,commission trade (fee,contract) | 116 | 109 | 107 |
52 | Retail trade (not motor veh) repairs | 105 | 104 | 108 |
55 | Hotels,restaurants | 95 | 101 | 104 |
60 | Transport by land,pipeline | 101 | 105 | 108 |
61 | Water transport | 104 | 132 | 109 |
62 | Air transport | 104 | 107 | 100 |
63 | Aux transport activ.,travel agents | 111 | 104 | 104 |
64 | Post,telecommunications | 111 | 106 | 106 |
65-67 | Financial services | 112 | 106 | 102 |
72 | Computer,related activities | 112 | 112 | 102 |
73 | Research,development | 98 | 103 | |
74 | Other business activities | 110 | 103 | 101 |
90-93 | Other services | 99 | 101 | 105 |
01-74; 90-93 | TOTAL market sectors | 102 | 103 | 105 |
Note: Derived from Mason, O’Leary, O’Mahony and Robinson (2006) See text in Section 5.2 for details of calculations.
Appendix - Sources and Methods#
A1 Principal data sources#
A1.1 Output measures
For the UK National Accounts data on current price gross output and value added were derived from the Office of National Statistics (ONS) Blue Book (2006) and ONS Supply-Use Tables 1995-2004. Real value added series were then derived using chain-linked volume indices published in the Blue Book and unpublished industry-specific output deflators supplied by ONS.
For New Zealand data on current price gross output and value added were derived from the National Accounts (Revised): Year ended March 2005. The conversion of March year data to a calendar year basis was far from straightforward. Statistics NZ supplied quarterly data on gross domestic product by industry in the form of a seasonally-adjusted chain-volume series expressed in 1995-96 prices (ie, in prices relating to the 12 months ending March 31, 1996) together with a quarterly Producers Price Index - Output series disaggregated by industry. These two data series were used to generate an industry-level current price value added index on a calendar year basis. However, the problem still arose of how to estimate a set of current-price starting values for this series. In the event current price value added totals for the calendar year 1995 were assumed to consist of 25% of current price value added for the 12 months ending March 1995 plus 75% of current price value added for the 12 months ending March 1996. The precision of our productivity comparisons could therefore be improved if quarterly data on current price value added disaggregated by industry could be made available.
In both countries output deflators for aggregate market sectors were calculated using a Tornqvist index formula with sector-level deflators weighted by each sector’s average share of total current price value added in adjacent years.
A1.2 Labour input measures
For UK employment ONS Blue Book totals at broad industry level were taken as control totals and then disaggregated to more detailed sector level using data on employment shares from the Annual Business Inquiry. Industry-level data on average annual hours worked per person engaged (including unpaid overtime) in the UK were derived from analysis of Labour Force Survey data.
For New Zealand the most reliable data series on labour inputs, described in Statistics New Zealand (2006b), shows total hours paid in a reference week in the middle of each quarter, including the self-employed as well as employees. Estimates of total annual hours worked by industry were obtained by summing the four weekly hours paid figures for each year, multiplying by 13 and then making a further adjustment to an hours worked basis, using an aggregate market sectors ratio of hours worked to hours paid derived from NZ Household Labour Force Survey (HLFS) data. This procedure was carried out on the advice of Statistics NZ because of concerns about lack of robustness at industry level in the HLFS hours worked series.
Remaining concerns about the comparability of labour input data concern the treatment of annual leave and other forms of absence from work in each country. The New Zealand hours worked series is based on responses collected over 52 weeks of the year and should therefore capture all forms of absence from work (paid or unpaid). For the UK the Labour Force Survey data on actual hours worked by survey respondents refer to a specified reference week which is usually the week prior to each interview. In general, LFS estimates are believed to take reasonable account of reduced working hours due to annual leave and statutory holidays and LFS methodological notes refer to procedures for some interviews falling during the Christmas/New Year period. Hence, it is likely that the UK estimates take much the same account of annual leave and other absences from work as do the New Zealand estimates.
A1.3 Labour share of value added
For the UK estimates of the labour share of value added at industry level were derived from Annual Business Inquiry data on employee compensation and value added, with an upward adjustment to take account of self-employed persons based on estimates of the ratio of self-employed to employees derived from Labour Force Surveys.
For New Zealand the labour share of value added at industry level was estimated in a similar manner using National Accounts data on employee compensation and value added at industry level, with an upward adjustment to take account of self-employed persons based on estimates of the ratio of self-employed to employees in the SNZ hours paid labour volume series described above.
For both countries we assume that self-employed hourly earnings are 70% of average hourly wages for employees. This procedure follows an approach suggested in O’Mahony and van Ark (2003) in the light of US evidence of generally lower compensation for self-employed persons compared to employees.
A1.4 Capital stocks
Capital stocks series were constructed using a perpetual inventory method that cumulates constant price investments and deducts the value of depreciated assets. Capital investment data at industry level were provided by the UK Office for National Statistics and Statistics New Zealand. In order to derive comparable estimates of productive capital stocks in New Zealand and the UK, common sector-specific depreciation rates (based on US estimates) were applied to the investment data in each country. Five asset types were distinguished: structures (non-residential buildings and other construction), computers, other plant and machinery, vehicles and intangibles (defined in the UK as consisting of patents, mineral exploration, artistic originals and the value of computer software). Investment data in national currencies were converted to US$ using OECD PPPs for investment goods by asset type. Finally, starting values for capital stocks were required in order to implement the perpetual inventory formula. In the UK starting values were set in 1948 by raising investment for that year by a factor equal to 0.5* (1/dj) where dj denotes the depreciation rate for asset type j.[14] In New Zealand the starting year for applying this formula ranged from 1859 for buildings to 1964 for computers.
Thus letting c denote types of capital, with I denoting investment and d the (geometric) depreciation rate, capital stocks were measured as:
The growth in aggregate capital was then calculated using a Tornqvist index formula, with weights equal to the share of each asset type in the total value of capital.
The assumption of geometric depreciation rates has the advantage that it is easy to implement. Its main disadvantage is that assets are depreciated rapidly at the beginning of the asset’s life but depreciation then tails off subsequently. This assumption is more reasonable for assets where technological change is rapid than it is for assets such as structures.
Estimated productive capital stocks were initially supplied for New Zealand in constant price 1995-96 NZ$ and for the UK in 2002 constant price £ sterling. Both these series were converted to constant price 1999 US$ using 1999 OECD PPPs for non-ICT investment goods by asset type along with deflators based on movements in investment goods producer price indices in the UK, US and New Zealand. For computers and software (assumed to be representative of intangibles), US ICT capital stock deflators were used, obtained from http://www.csls.ca/data/ict.asp
Notes#
- [14]This is based on the idea that about 50% of an asset is depreciated within half its average life length. This kind of assumption is reasonable if the starting value is a long time before the capital stocks are employed in analysis (in this study 1995).
A2 Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) exchange rates#
For the UK sector-level PPP exchange rate estimates for 2002 were derived by updating estimates of 1997 PPPs in O’Mahony (1999) using OECD 1999 expenditure PPPs and output deflators for the UK and the US. For New Zealand a new set of sector-level PPP estimates for 1997 were prepared by Gerard Ypma at the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC). They comprise a mix of unit value ratios (UVRs) calculated as sales of products divided by quantities produced UVRs and expenditure PPPs adjusted for relative trade and transportation margins and for taxes. These GGDC PPPs were updated to 2002 on the basis of producer price changes at sector level between 1997-2002 in New Zealand and the US, with additional adjustments for electricity, gas and water, wholesale and retail based on updated 1999 OECD expenditure PPPs in order to make the New Zealand PPPs for those industries more comparable with UK PPPs.
The basic GGDC approach to such estimates is as follows: European Union countries are compared on the basis of unit values, etc., derived from Prodcom, which is Eurostat’s collective database of production censuses. All EU countries are compared bilaterally to Germany because it has the largest coverage. Germany is then compared bilaterally with the U.S., as are all other non-EU OECD countries. At industry level the results are then multilateralised using an Elteto-Köves-Szulc (EKS) weighting procedure. Therefore, in order to incorporate New Zealand into this multi-country PPP dataset, New Zealand output prices were systematically compared with those of the U.S. for a selected benchmark year. The same exercise was also carried out for Australia in order to facilitate the sensitivity tests described in Section 4 of the main text. The main sources used in this exercise are listed in Table A2.1
In an effort to develop criteria for deciding which type of PPP should best be used for cross-country sector-level productivity comparisons, GGDC researchers have recently analysed Supply-Use Tables for a number of countries to identify how expenditure prices and output prices are related. This analysis has then been used to develop a new dataset of industry PPPs for 45 industries and 25 countries for the year 1997. Time series are then applied to update and backdate over time from this benchmark year. Full details of this dataset are provided in van Ark and Timmer (2001) and van Ark, Stuivenwold and Inklaar (2003).
In order to derive time series of New Zealand-UK ALP comparisons, we use ‘constant PPPs’ (estimated for 2002 and then updated and backdated using sectoral price deflators for both New Zealand and the UK relative to the US). This approach is preferred for estimates of productivity growth rates as the underlying price deflators are explicitly designed to capture changes through time. A disadvantage is that the weights employed to aggregate prices up to total market economy level do not vary though time, in contrast to a ‘current PPPs’ approach where the basket of goods and services that is priced changes annually. However, a current PPPs approach also has disadvantages, for example, revisions and methodological changes in the OECD-Eurostat PPP programme have contributed to considerable instability in data series based on current PPPs (Lau and Wallis, 2005).
Appendix Table A2.17 - Sources for PPP estimates for New Zealand, Australia and US
3-digit Gross Output set for 1997
- -OECD STAN Database 2004
- -Statistics New Zealand, Input-output table 95/96, Table 2 Use
- -Statistics New Zealand, Rest of the Economy Survey 1996
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australia, Input-Output table 1997
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics, Input-Output tables Product details 1996-1997
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics (2003), Mineral Production, Quantity and Value by State, 2001-02 and 2002-03
- -Groningen Growth and Development Centre, 60-Industry Database, October 2005, http://www.ggdc.net
- -OECD, Structural Statistics for Industry and Services
Agriculture
- FAOSTAT database, FAO prices and quantities for 1997
Mining
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics (2003), Mineral Production, Quantity and Value by State, 2001-02 and 2002-03
- -United Nations, 2001 Industrial Commodity Statistics Yearbook
- -Statistics New Zealand, ACPs by ANZSCC
- - Statistical Abstract of the United States 1999
- -1997 US Census of Manufactures,
Manufacturing
- -ICP PPPs and nominal values for basic headings for 1996 and 1999 from the OECD/Eurostat workgroup
- - OECD (1999), Consumption Tax Trends, 1999 edition, Paris
- - OECD and International Energy Agency (1999), Energy policies of IEA countries, 1999 review, Paris.
- -OECD STAN Database 2004
- -Trade Margins from Trade PPP calculations (see below)
- -Groningen Growth and Development Centre, 60-Industry Database, October 2005, http://www.ggdc.net
- - U.S. Census of Manufactures 1997
- - Mulligen, P.H. Van (2002), Quality Differences And Hedonic Pricing In International Comparisons, Ph.D. Thesis, University Of Groningen.
Utilities
- -United Nations, 1998 Energy Statistics Yearbook
- -FAO, Aquastat Database 2002
- -International Energy Agency’s Energy Prices & Taxes (2nd quarter 2006)
- -ICP PPPs and nominal values for basic headings for 1996 and 1999 from the OECD/Eurostat workgroup
Trade
- -Statistics New Zealand, Annual Enterprise Survey - NZSIC-Based Financial Estimates and Sample Errors, 1995/96 Financial Year
- -Statistics New Zealand, Actual Retail Sales By Quarter By Storetype, http://www.stats.govt.nz/domino/external/PASFull/pasfull.nsf/0/73250640e09aeaca4c25671a0016ba13/$FILE/alltabls.xls [Treasury adjusted URL at 04 Mar 2024: https://infoshare.stats.govt.nz/SelectVariables.aspx?pxID=5ba1af3c-7f13-4b89-84d0-1692ea345826]
- -US Bureau of Census, 1997 Economic Census
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics, Wholesale Industry Australia, 1998-1999, 2.1 Selected Income items by industry
- -Australian Bureau of Statistics, Retail Industry Australia, 1998-1999, 2.1 Selected Income items by industry
Transport
- -World Bank Railway Database
- -ICAO, Civil Aviation Statistics of the World 1997
- -United Nations, Annual Bulletin of Statistics for Europe and North America 1999
- -OECD, Structural Statistics for Industry and Services
- - Universal Postal Union, Universal Postal Database 2004
- - OECD, Telecommunication Database 2003
- -Bolland, Weir and Vincent (2005), Development of a New Zealand National Freight Matrix
- -U.S. Department of Transportation, Bureau of Transportation Statistics (2002), National Transportation Statistics 2002, BTS02-08, Washington, DC, U.S. Government Printing Office, December 2002
- -Statistics New Zealand, Input-output table 95/96, Table 2 Use
- -Statistics New Zealand, Rest of the Economy Survey 1996
- - Statistics New Zealand, National Accounts 2004
- - Statistics New Zealand, NZ Statistical Yearbook 1998
- - United Nations ESCAP, Asia-Pacific Transport Database, Transport and Tourism Division
- - Institute of Shipping Economics and Logistics (1999), Shipping Statistics Yearbook 1999
- - Bureau of Economic Analysis, 1997 Benchmark Use Table
- - Australasian Railway Association-personal communications.
- - Australian Bureau of Statistics, Survey of Motor Vehicle Use, Australia, 2000 (9208.0)
- - Australian Bureau of Statistics, Input-Output tables Product details 1996-1997
- - Quantas Annual report 1997
- - OECD STAN Database 2005, rev. 2
Other Industries
- -ICP PPPs and nominal values for basic headings for 1996 and 1999 from the OECD/Eurostat workgroup
- - OECD (1999), Consumption Tax Trends, 1999 edition, Paris
- -Groningen Growth and Development Centre, 60-Industry Database, October 2005, http://www.ggdc.net
- - OECD STAN Database 2005, rev. 2
Statistics New Zealand, Input-output table 95/96, Table 2 Use
A3 Labour quality measurement#
Our approach to estimating and comparing average labour quality in New Zealand and the UK is described in detail in Section 5.2 of the main text. To recapitulate, this measure was derived by benchmarking on graduate-level qualifications (where comparability across countries is at its strongest), and then using ratios of mean wages in non-graduate categories to mean graduate wages in each country as indicators of labour quality differences between the respective categories.
For the UK estimates of qualification shares at industry level were derived from Labour Force Surveys 1995-2004. Following advice from NZ Statistics, estimates of employment shares by qualification group at sector level in New Zealand were based on the NZ Income Survey (NZIS) which is believed to collect higher quality data on qualifications than the NZ Census. It is also an advantage for comparative purposes that the NZIS is based on an interviewer-administered questionnaire as is the Labour Force Survey in the UK. However, since the qualifications data in the NZIS are only available at a relatively high level of sectoral aggregation, more disaggregated sectoral estimates did have to be based on NZ Census data for 1996 and 2001. In addition NZIS data were only available for 1997-2004 so the estimated series was backdated to 1995 on the basis of rates of change between 1997-99.
Data on weekly pay in the UK Labour Force Survey and annual pay in the NZIS were also used to derive estimates of qualification-related wage differentials for full-time workers for aggregate manufacturing and aggregate market services in each country. The focus on full-time workers is necessary since we do not have access to hourly wage data in either country which would be conceptually preferable as an indicator of productivity. These wage data for manufacturing and market services were then used to weight employment shares by qualification group in relevant sectors; for agriculture, mining, utilities and construction, employment shares were weighted by the wage differentials for aggregate market sectors. Table A3.2 below shows a fair degree of stability over time in the wage ratios for aggregate market sectors in each country, with the exception of the years 2003-04 in New Zealand when the survey data suggest a widening of the pay gap between graduates and non-graduates.
This approach constitutes a distinct advance on skill measures based on education inputs (eg, years of schooling) or attainments which make no effort to take account of productivity differences. However, the measure used here relies on two key assumptions (1) that relative mean pay by qualification group is reflective of productivity differences and (2) that graduate-level productivity is comparable across countries. Furthermore, as noted in Section 5.2 above, there are many concerns regarding New Zealand data on qualification levels and mean wages by qualifications group (partly due to small cell sizes in the surveys concerned). Hence, our estimates of relative labour quality need to be treated with due caution.
A more complex version of our labour quality measure would take account of inter-country differences in the age-distribution of workers in each qualification group since age is generally correlated with work experience and opportunities for on-the-job skills acquisition. Hyslop, Mare and Timmins (2003) point out that the proportion of New Zealand workers holding degree-level qualifications roughly doubled between 1986 and 2001. This means that recent increases in qualifications are concentrated in younger (less experienced) age groups which may tend to reduce the wage premia attached to degree-level qualifications. It is beyond the scope of this paper to explore New Zealand-UK differences in this respect in detail. However, it is worth noting that the UK has experienced similar rapid growth in the graduate share of employment since the 1980s which has persisted into the early 2000s (Table A3.1).
Appendix Table A3.18 -Employment in aggregate market sectors, analysed by qualifications category, 1995-2004
A: UK
Graduates | NVQ 3-4 | NVQ 1-2 | No qualifications above NVQ1 level | Total | |
1995 | 12 | 36 | 35 | 18 | 100 |
1996 | 12 | 36 | 35 | 17 | 100 |
1997 | 12 | 36 | 36 | 15 | 100 |
1998 | 13 | 36 | 36 | 14 | 100 |
1999 | 14 | 37 | 36 | 14 | 100 |
2000 | 15 | 37 | 35 | 13 | 100 |
2001 | 15 | 37 | 35 | 13 | 100 |
2002 | 15 | 37 | 35 | 12 | 100 |
2003 | 16 | 37 | 35 | 12 | 100 |
2004 | 16 | 37 | 35 | 12 | 100 |
B: New Zealand
Graduates | Post-secondary school qualifications below Bachelor level | No post-school qualifications | Total | |
1995 | 9 | 37 | 54 | 100 |
1996 | 9 | 37 | 54 | 100 |
1997 | 10 | 38 | 52 | 100 |
1998 | 10 | 38 | 52 | 100 |
1999 | 11 | 38 | 51 | 100 |
2000 | 10 | 38 | 51 | 100 |
2001 | 11 | 39 | 50 | 100 |
2002 | 11 | 38 | 51 | 100 |
2003 | 12 | 37 | 51 | 100 |
2004 | 13 | 37 | 50 | 100 |
Sources: UK Labour Force Survey, NZ Income Survey and NZ Census of Population and Dwellings.
Appendix Table A3.29 - Pay differentials by qualification categories in aggregate market sectors, 1995-2004 (Index numbers: Mean graduate pay=1)
A: UK
NVQ 3-4 | NVQ 1-2 | No qualifications above NVQ1 level |
|
1995 | 0.67 | 0.53 | 0.47 |
1996 | 0.67 | 0.53 | 0.47 |
1997 | 0.67 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
1998 | 0.67 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
1999 | 0.67 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
2000 | 0.66 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
2001 | 0.66 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
2002 | 0.66 | 0.53 | 0.46 |
2003 | 0.66 | 0.54 | 0.47 |
2004 | 0.67 | 0.54 | 0.47 |
B: New Zealand
Post-secondary school qualifications below Bachelor level |
No post-school qualifications |
|
1995 | 0.73 | 0.60 |
1996 | 0.73 | 0.60 |
1997 | 0.74 | 0.60 |
1998 | 0.74 | 0.60 |
1999 | 0.73 | 0.60 |
2000 | 0.73 | 0.60 |
2001 | 0.72 | 0.60 |
2002 | 0.72 | 0.59 |
2003 | 0.71 | 0.58 |
2004 | 0.70 | 0.56 |
Sources: UK Labour Force Survey and NZ Income Survey.