Formats and related files
Abstract#
This paper provides estimates of individual and aggregate revenue elasticities of income and consumption taxes in New Zealand, based on the 2001 tax structure and expenditure patterns. Using analytical expressions for revenue elasticities at the individual and aggregate levels, together with a simulated income distribution, values for New Zealand were obtained. Results using equi-proportional income changes suggest that the aggregate income and consumption tax revenue elasticities are both fairly constant as mean income increases, at around 1.3 and 0.95 respectively. This latter estimate assumes that increases in disposable income are accompanied by approximately proportional increases in total expenditure. If there is a tendency for the savings proportion to increase as disposable income increases, a somewhat lower total consumption tax revenue elasticity, of around 0.9, is obtained for 2001 income levels. However, non-equiproportional income changes are more realistic. Allowing for regression towards the geometric mean income reduces these elasticities, giving an elasticity for income and consumption taxes combined that is only slightly above unity. Examination of the tax-share weighted expenditure elasticities for various goods also revealed that, despite the adoption of a broad based GST at a uniform rate in New Zealand, the persistence of various excises has an important effect on the overall consumption tax revenue elasticity, especially for individuals at relatively low income levels.
Acknowledgements#
We are grateful to Matthew Bell for providing the regression results for incomes in consecutive years, and for helpful general discussions on tax revenue forecasting. This paper was written while Gemmell was a Visiting Research Fellow at the New Zealand Treasury.
Disclaimer#
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the New Zealand Treasury. The paper is presented not as policy, but with a view to inform and stimulate wider debate.
1 Introduction#
This paper provides estimates of the built-in flexibility, or revenue elasticity, of income and consumption taxes (GST and excise taxes) in New Zealand. It is important for the design of tax policy to be able to measure reliably the income elasticity of tax revenues both for a tax system and its component taxes. For example, given some revenue target, the need for discretionary changes tax rates and thresholds depends on the expected automatic revenue growth generated by the system’s built-in flexibility. The extent to which the aggregate effective tax rate changes when total income changes depends on a range of factors, including consumption patterns and the distribution of individual relative income changes associated with the aggregate change. Furthermore, elasticity and progressivity are closely related, so that tax changes designed to affect progressivity may have unforeseen consequences for elasticity, and vice versa.
Elasticity values at individual and aggregate levels are reported. These are obtained using convenient analytical expressions which have the advantage that they can be evaluated readily from relatively little information about the tax structure, income distribution and budget shares. Furthermore, the main factors affecting the size of the elasticities can be identified, using meaningful and easily interpreted decompositions of the revenue elasticities.[1]
Detailed official forecasts of tax revenues in New Zealand are of course frequently made, though for various reasons these do not always involve the explicit calculation of revenue elasticities. Few independent estimates for New Zealand appear to have been published; however, various elasticities are given by van den Noord (2000) for OECD countries.
This neglect may reflect the perception that, in the presence of lower rates of inflation in recent years, a flattening of the income tax structure, and a broad based consumption tax, fiscal drag is no longer significant. However, as the analysis below shows, the issue is more complex than this simple view would suggest. It is also useful to identify the various influences on the size of New Zealand tax revenue elasticities.
Section 2 sets out the relevant conceptual expressions for income and consumption tax revenue elasticities at the individual level; subsection 2 provides some estimates based on the 2001 tax structure. Section 3 defines aggregate revenue elasticity expressions, with empirical estimates in subsection 2. These estimates use the standard assumption that all incomes increase by the same proportion from year to year. Subsection 3 models the more realistic case of non-equiproportional income changes, and allows for a simple process of regression towards the geometric mean income.
In producing aggregate values directly from individual values, the question arises of the level of disaggregation to be used, particularly regarding the budget shares. The estimates reported here are based on an overall distribution of taxable income and use published budget shares for all households combined, rather than considering different household types separately; however, the methods could be applied to more disagreggated data. Section 4 draws some conclusions.
Notes
- [1]The approach, involving explicit modelling of the tax structure, contrasts with the use of regression analyses, of time series data on tax revenues and income, which are sometimes used to produce aggregate elasticities. Some comparisons of aggregate income tax revenue elasticities based both on regressions and on tax-share weighted individual values are given in Giorno et al. (1995), although they do not include New Zealand.
2 Individual revenue elasticities#
This section examines tax revenue elasticities for individuals. The variation in individual elasticities with income provides a useful independent indication of the local progressivity of the tax structure, and of course the individual elasticities provide the basic components on which aggregate values are based. The appropriate formulae are given in subsection 1, and empirical estimates for the 2001 tax structure in New Zealand are reported in subsection 2.
2.1 Elasticity formulae#
Suppose
denotes the income tax paid by individual
with a nominal income of
Changes in nominal income with respect to nominal tax allowances affect built-in flexibility.[2] The revenue elasticity of the income tax with respect to a change in individual income,
is defined as:
(1)
where
is the marginal tax rate and
is the average tax rate faced by
. Here, the first subscript of the revenue elasticity,
refers to the type of tax revenue considered (so that in the present case of the individual elasticity, the
subscript is dropped for convenience) and the second subscript refers to the income (or tax base) that is considered to change. In a progressive tax structure,
for all
so that
This elasticity is also a local measure of progressivity: it is the concept of liability progression defined by Musgrave and Thin (1948).
Consider an individual with gross income of
and facing a multi-step income tax function, such that if
the tax paid is
; if
tax paid is
; if
tax paid is
and so on. Hence if
falls into the
th tax bracket, so that
and
income tax can be expressed for
as:
(2)
where
Hence the tax paid under a multi-step function is equivalent to that paid with a single-step tax structure having a marginal rate,
imposed on the individual’s income in excess of an effective threshold of
Creedy and Gemmell (2003) show that, for this tax function, the individual elasticity,
is:
(3)
This indicates the potentially important role of the elasticity of effective allowances,
. The individual revenue elasticity must exceed unity if
. A positive value of
can be expected where allowances are income-related, for example when there is tax relief for mortgage interest payments or pension contributions.[3]
To derive the individual revenue elasticity for consumption taxes, define
as individual
’s net income, so that:
(4)
Suppose a proportion,
, of
is consumed, so that total consumption expenditure,
is
In general,
can vary with
and hence with
, and can exceed unity over some ranges of
as discussed below.
If the tax-exclusive ad valorem indirect tax rate imposed on the
th good (for
is
the equivalent tax-inclusive rate is
. Define
as person
’s budget share of the
th good. The consumption tax paid by person
on good
can be written as:
(5)
It is required to obtain the consumption tax revenue elasticity for each good, that is,
. Writing
as expenditure on the
th good, first note that:
(6)
implies:
implies:
implies
Differentiating (5) with respect to income,
and using the relationships in (6), it can be shown that:
(7)
where
is the elasticity of disposable income,
, with respect to
. The second term in (7) can be expressed in terms of
, the total expenditure elasticity of demand for the
th good by person
, whereby:
(8)
The last term in (7),
, is determined by the progressivity of the income tax, such that:
(9)
In fact,
is the familiar measure of residual progression. Combining (7), (8) and (9) it follows that:
(10)
Equation (10) demonstrates that the consumption tax revenue elasticity for good
can be decomposed into three terms, reflecting the total expenditure elasticity for good
, the way in which the proportion of disposable income consumed by
changes with income, and the degree of residual progression determined by individual
’s marginal and average income tax rates.
The consumption tax revenue elasticity for all goods combined, for person
, can be obtained directly from the expression for the consumption tax paid on all goods,
. Aggregating (5) over
goods gives:
(11)
Differentiation of (11) then reveals that
is given by:
(12)
This result shows that, compared with the revenue elasticity for a single good in (10), the tax-share weighted expenditure elasticity appears in (12). To calculate the weighted elasticity, it is necessary to distinguish only between goods facing different ad valorum tax rates.
The elasticity of the consumption proportion with respect to income in (10), , also varies with incomes if saving rates vary across disposable income levels. While a non-proportional relationship is generally accepted for cross-sectional income differences and, to a lesser extent, for time-series changes over the short-term, changes in the consumption proportion over the long-run are probably best regarded as proportional.
Creedy and Gemmell (2003) allow for the possibility of a non-proportional relationship by using the specification:[4]
(13)
For this case, it can be shown that
in (12) is equal to
. Hence for a proportional consumption function (including zero savings, where
),
. The elasticity therefore depends on the three terms as follows:
(14)
The first two bracketed terms of equation (14) are less than or equal to unity, but the third component, shown in curly brackets, may exceed unity for some income levels and tax structures. However,
tends towards unity as income increases.[5]
Notes
- [2]The exception is where the tax function is homogeneous of degree one in income and allowances, and both are indexed similarly.
- [3]For example, Creedy and Gemmell (2003) found that takes values around 0.4 for the UK, but varies significantly over time in response to changes in the tax deductability of various income-related reliefs suchas those for families,pensions and mortgages. The value of is of course unlikely to exceed unity.
- [4]The over-spending at very low income levels can be viewed in terms of the existence of transfer payments and consumption out of savings.
- [5]This is because all expenditure elasticities converge towards unity, although the convergence may not be monotonic, along with the first two terms in (14). Creedy and Gemmell (2003a) illustrate this decomposition for the UK.
2.2 Estimates of individual revenue elasticities#
Individual elasticities can identify those taxpayers likely to experience the greatest change in tax liabilities as their incomes, or fiscal parameters, change. They therefore also provide local measures of tax progressivity. This subsection shows how individual revenue elasticities can be expected to vary across income levels in New Zealand.
Using information on the New Zealand income tax structure in 2001 to calculate effective allowances,
estimates of the income tax revenue elasticity in (3) can readily be obtained for a range of individual income levels. Income tax rates of 0.15, 0.21, 0.33, 0.39 between income thresholds of (NZ$) 0, 9500, 38000, and 60000 were used. These are the effective rates and thresholds, allowing for the existence of the Low-Income Rebate. For New Zealand, with no initial tax-free allowance and virtually no deductions, tax thresholds do not change with individuals’ incomes, so it is reasonable to assume
in (3). This simplifies income tax revenue elasticity calculations.
Consumption tax revenue elasticity calculations require estimates of the ad valorum-equivalent indirect tax rates. Most goods are taxed at the 12.5 per cent GST rate. However some expenditures are exempt from GST (for example, rent and overseas travel) while a number of excises produce very different effective tax rates on goods such as fuel, alcohol and tobacco. The consumption tax rates used are given in the Appendix.
It is necessary to have total expenditure elasticities of goods taxed at different rates. For this reason it is not possible, even if separate income unit data from budget studies were available, to produce precise individual values since estimates must be based on the cross-sectional variation in budget shares as total expenditure varies within specified groups (defined say by location or demographic characteristics). The estimates reported here are based on total expenditure elasticities for all households combined, and were obtained from published average expenditures from the 2000-2001 Household Expenditure Survey; further details of the method used are discussed in the Appendix.
Finally, consumption function parameters,
and
in (13) are required. In view of the considerable difficulty in obtaining reliable information about savings functions, three consumption function cases were examined. These are: the no savings case,
; the proportional savings case,
; and the non-proportional case,
,
. The proportional case assumes that 95 per cent of disposable income is spent, while the non-proportional case implies an average propensity to consume of 0.95 at NZ$30,000, which is around the arithmetic mean income level.
Figure 1 shows how the income and consumption tax revenue elasticity (all goods) varies across income levels. The income tax elasticity generally declines as income rises, with discrete jumps taking place as individuals cross the tax thresholds, reflecting the sharp increase in the marginal rate of income tax.
For the consumption tax elasticity, two examples of the proportional and non-proportional cases are shown. As shown in subsection 1, the shapes of these profiles reflect the three combined effects of the progressivity of the income tax, saving habits and differing expenditure elasticities across goods (combined with their associated ad valorem rates). Income tax progressivity tends to induce a ‘mirror image’ effect in the consumption tax profile via changes in disposable incomes. For example, discrete declines are evident in the consumption tax elasticity profiles in Figure 1 at the income tax thresholds and, at higher income levels, elasticities tend to rise.
However, at lower income levels consumption tax revenue elasticities also decline, rather than showing a mirror image of the decline in the income tax elasticity. This arises because of the dominant effect of declines in the tax-share weighted expenditure elasticities. For example, examination of these elasticities in Figure 2 reveals substantial declines in tax-share weighted expenditure elasticities for vehicles (mainly fuel) and tobacco as incomes increase from relatively low levels. Since these expenditures face especially high tax rates, changes in these tax-share weighted elasticities dominate changes in the weighted average at low income levels. Figure 1 also reveals that the elasticities produced by the non-proportional consumption function relationship are generally slightly lower, by about 0.1 - 0.2 percentage points, than the proportional equivalents.
3 Aggregate revenue elasticities#
This section examines aggregate tax revenue elasticities, which are the most relevant from the point of view of tax forecasting and planning, and possible automatic stabilisation properties of the tax structure. Subsection 1 presents the basic formulae required and subsection 2 reports results for New Zealand in the case of equiproportional income changes. The implications of non-equiproportional income changes are examined in subsection 3.
3.1 Elasticity formulae#
Aggregate revenue elasticities can readily be expressed as a tax-weighted sum of the individual elasticities. Letting
and
denote respectively total income tax revenue and total income, the aggregate income tax revenue elasticity is:
(15)
Evaluation of the aggregate elasticity therefore requires, in addition to information about the income distribution (for computation of the income tax shares
), knowledge of the extent to which individuals’ incomes change when aggregate income changes, reflected in the term
where the condition
must hold. A typical simplifying assumption is that all incomes increase by the same proportion, so that
and the aggregate income rax revenue elasticity is a simple tax-share weighted average of individual values.
The aggregate consumption tax elasticity can be calculated, following (15), using:
(16)
where
is aggregate consumption tax revenue. Furthermore, since total revenue is
the elasticity of total revenue with respect to aggregate income can be found as a tax-share weighted average of the income and consumption tax revenue elasticities.
3.2 Estimates of aggregate revenue elasticities#
This subsection uses the analytical expressions in subsection 1, along with the assumption of equiproportional income changes, to examine how aggregate revenue elasticities vary with aggregate income levels in New Zealand.
One approach would be to use detailed information, in the form of a large data set containing data on individual taxable incomes.[6] However, the method used here (since such individual data are available only to a highly restricted group of users in New Zealand) is to parameterise the distribution, based on grouped income distribution data, and then to produce a simulated distribution of incomes by taking random draws from the fitted distribution.
Figure 5 in the appendix shows the New Zealand grouped income distribution in 2001, and discusses the application of a lognormal distribution to summarise the data.[7] It was found that a mean and variance of the logarithms of incomes of
and
provide a reasonable approximation to parameterise a lognormal income distribution. These values imply an arithmetic mean income of $26,903.[8] Each aggregate revenue elasticity is obtained using a simulated population of 20,000 individuals, drawn at random from the distribution. As the results reported here assume that all incomes increase by the same proportion, the relative dispersion of incomes remains constant as incomes change over time.
Figure 3 shows aggregate elasticity profiles for income and all consumption taxes, and for total tax revenues, as incomes increase over a range of average income levels.[9] The consumption tax profile shown is for the non-proportional consumption case. These profiles are approximately linear with the income and consumption tax elasticities at slightly below 1.3 and 0.9 respectively. However, the income tax elasticity reveals a tendency to rise slightly and then decline at higher average income levels. This decline occurs when a large proportion of the income distribution faces the highest marginal income tax rate.[10]
Figure 4 shows how consumption tax elasticities depend on assumed saving behaviour. Revenue elasticity estimates are noticeably higher for the proportional consumption and ‘no savings’ cases (profiles A and B), but decline more rapidly as income rises, compared to the non-proportional case in profile C. For example, at mean income levels of around $30,000, elasticities of about 1.0 and slightly below 0.9 are obtained from profiles A and C respectively. Figure 4 also suggests that the effect on the revenue elasticity of ignoring savings is not substantial provided, when income increases, the proportion of income consumed remains approximately constant.
Notes
- [6]Some studies use an entirely numerical approach, by imposing small income increases on each individual in the data set and examining the resulting tax changes, rather than using explicit formulae such as those given above.
- [7]In Giorno et al. (1995), aggregate income tax revenue elasticities were obtained by fitting lognormal distributions, using information for each country about only the ratios of the first and ninth deciles to the median income. Values of individual elasticities were computed at 16 points on the income distribution. An aggregate elasticity was obtained as the ratio of average (income weighted) marginal rates to that of average (income weighted) average tax rates. (The weights were obtained from the first moment distribution of the associated lognormal distribution). Unfortunately the ratio of averages is not equivalent to the average of ratios, which is the required measure.
- [8]In the lognormal case, the arithmetic mean income is derived as
- [9]The 20k values were selected randomly from an initial distribution with a lower mean of logarithms than the 2001 distribution. The average income increase, with a fixed variance of logarithms of income, was achieved simply by increasing all incomes by a fixed proportion each year. The non-equiproportional case involves a more complex process of income change, as shown below.
- [10]For the highest average income shown, about one quarter of taxpayers are above the top threshold.
3.3 Non-equiproportional income changes#
This subsection relaxes the assumption of equiproportionate income changes, used in the previous subsection and in the vast majority of studies. In line with the present approach of using parametric specifications at a fairly high level of aggregation, subsection 1 presents a function to describe the systematic variation in
with
Subsection 2 presents revised aggregate elasticities based on estimates of the dynamic specification.
3.3.1 A specification
It is convenient to specify a functional form for the variation in
with
. A suitable form, involving just one parameter, is:
(17)
where
is the mean of logarithms of income (the logarithm of geometric mean income).[11] This means that if
and
is less than geometric mean income, the elasticity,
is greater than unity, and vice versa, so that (17) involves equalising changes. If
income changes are disequalising. This specification can thus be used to examine the sensitivity of aggregate revenue elasticity measures to variations in the standard assumption of
.[12]
In examining non-equiproportionate changes, according to equation (17), it is also useful, when increasing the 20,000 simulated incomes from one year to the next, to impose random proportionate income changes, in addition to the systematic equalising or disequalising tendency reflected in
. Without such changes, annual income inequality changes too rapidly. The specification in (17) is consistent with the following dynamic process. Let
denote individual
’s income in period
, and let
denote the mean of logarithms in period
, with
as the geometric mean. The generating process can be written as:
(18)
where
is
. Equation (18) can be rewritten as:
(19)
Hence the variance of logarithms of income in period 2,
, is given by
(20)
The variance of logarithms is therefore constant when
.[13]
3.3.2 Aggregate elasticities
Estimation of equation (19) was carried out for a range of pairs of consecutive years during the 1990s, using information from large samples of IR5 and IR3 filers. The results suggest a relatively stable value of
of around
. This reflects a substantial degree of regression towards the (geometric) mean; indeed, with no random component of income change this would have the effect of halving income inequality in as little as three years. If
is combined with
the variance of logariths of income remains constant over time.[14] These values produce an aggregate income tax revenue elasticity, at 2001 mean income, of about
. For the proportional and non-proportional consumption functions respectively, the aggregate consumption tax revenue elasticities are
and
giving corresponding total tax revenue elasticities of
and
respectively.
Regression towards the geometric mean therefore reduces the aggregate revenue elasticities. This arises because, for those above the geometric mean income, the value of
is reduced, and vice versa for those below the geometric mean. The aggregate elasticity, from (15), is a tax-share weighted average of these terms, and in view of the fact that
increases as
increases, the lower values of
at the upper income levels dominate.
To give some idea of the sensitivity of results to the variation in
, consider a value of
which requires
for a stable degree of income inequality. The aggregate income tax elasticity, again at 2001 mean income, is now
while the consumption tax elasticities are
and
for proportional and non-proportional consumption functions (giving total revenue elasticities of
and
).
Notes
- [11]In the case of lognormal income distributions, this is also the median income.
- [12]For non-equiproportional changes, the aggregate revenue elasticity can now be less than 1; for example it is zero if the only incomes which increase are below a tax-free threshold and none crosses the threshold.
- [13]In general, the variance of logarithms of income increases if the regression coefficient, , exceeds the correlation between log-incomes in the two periods. If the variance of logarithms of incomes eventually becomes stable at . On dynamic income specifications, see Creedy (1985).
- [14]This value is in fact similar to that estimated for IR3 filers, though the values obtained for IR5 filers were lower, at about 0.1. Given that these samples do not constitute all taxpayers, and in practice inequality is relatively stable, it is appropriate here to model a stable variance of logarithms.
4 Conclusions#
This paper has examined the revenue responsiveness properties of New Zealand income and consumption taxes, based on the 2001 tax structure and expenditure patterns. Using analytical expressions for revenue elasticities at the individual and aggregate levels, together with a simulated income distribution, values for New Zealand were obtained. Treating income growth as equiproportionate, these suggest that the aggregate income and consumption tax revenue elasticities are both fairly constant as mean income increases, at around 1.3 and 1.0 respectively. This latter estimate assumes that increases in disposable income are accompanied by approximately proportional increases in total expenditure. Allowing for non-equiproportionate income growth reduces revenue elasticities to around 1.1 (income tax) and 0.93 (consumption taxes). If there is a tendency for the savings proportion to increase as disposable income increases, a somewhat lower total consumption tax revenue elasticity, of around 0.85 - 0.90, is obtained at mean income levels which approximate current levels in New Zealand. These elasticities are relatively low by international standards. Examination of the tax-share weighted expenditure elasticities for various goods also revealed that, despite the adoption of a broad based GST at a uniform rate in New Zealand, the persistence of various excises has an important effect on the overall consumption tax revenue elasticity, especially for individuals at relatively low income levels.
Appendix: Further details of the elasticity computations#
Expenditure elasticities
Expenditure elasticities were obtained using the published summary table of average expenditures over a range of income groups in the 2001 NZ Household Economic Survey (HES), obtained from http://www.stats.govt.nz/. This table divides all households in the sample into
income groups. Within each group the budget shares for each of
commodity groups were obtained (by dividing average expenditure in each category by average total expenditure).[15] Denote the arithmetic mean total expenditure of the
th group by
and the budget share of the
th commodity group and
th total expenditure group by
.
The raw values of these budget shares cannot be used to obtain elasticities because sampling variations (particularly for low and high income groups) give rise to negative elasticities. Regressions were carried out of the form:
(21)
for each commodity group,
. In addition to generally providing a good fit, this specification has the advantage that weights based on the estimated parameters add to unity.[16] The smoothed budget shares were then used to calculate the total expenditure elasticities.
Differentiating (21), and dropping the
subscript, gives:
(22)
so that
unequivocally falls as
rises if
and
or if
so long as
Alternatively, the share rises as income rises (that is, the income elasticity exceeds 1) if
and
or if
so long as
The coefficient estimates are reported in Appendix Tables 1 and 2. The required expenditure elasticities were obtained using:
(23)
with
taken from differentiation of (21).
a | b | c | R-squared | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Fruit | -0.00829 | 0.002749 | 2.087083 | 0.26022 |
Vegetables | 0.054475 | -0.00579 | -1.37903 | 0.794889 |
Meat | 0.225018 | -0.02806 | -13.3021 | 0.732829 |
Poultry | 0.052294 | -0.00617 | -3.62406 | 0.302579 |
Fish | 0.001745 | 0.000182 | 0.429412 | 0.195002 |
Farm products, fats, oils | 0.126825 | -0.0152 | -4.4229 | 0.869153 |
Cereals, cereal products | 0.135981 | -0.01589 | -5.7208 | 0.887933 |
Sweet products, beverages | 0.139186 | -0.01627 | -7.28867 | 0.713447 |
Other foodstuffs | 0.152218 | -0.01774 | -8.35408 | 0.381223 |
Meals away from home | -0.16374 | 0.03029 | 4.718327 | 0.971466 |
Rent | 0.622274 | -0.08312 | -1.83007 | 0.928584 |
Payments to local authorities | -0.0882 | 0.013836 | 15.20095 | 0.950052 |
Property maintenance goods | 0.081228 | -0.0069 | -8.63439 | 0.718421 |
Property maintenance | -0.68323 | 0.100973 | 43.35151 | 0.787053 |
Housing expenses n.e.c. | -0.03517 | 0.004634 | 3.377435 | 0.741892 |
Domestic fuel and power | 0.196174 | -0.02413 | -0.94521 | 0.976625 |
Home appliances | -0.00112 | 0.003079 | 2.134009 | 0.024083 |
Household equipment | -0.00563 | 0.001527 | 0.727346 | 0.041477 |
Furniture | -0.10488 | 0.017014 | 6.453542 | 0.741345 |
Furnishings | -0.00076 | 0.000831 | -0.64299 | 0.451658 |
Floor coverings | -0.06074 | 0.008517 | 4.952152 | 0.461902 |
Household textiles | -0.01107 | 0.002411 | 0.852601 | 0.124718 |
Household supplies | 0.078421 | -0.00923 | -4.4682 | 0.502538 |
Household services | -0.08467 | 0.015257 | 16.66589 | 0.919618 |
Men's clothing | -0.0772 | 0.01134 | 5.588882 | 0.523455 |
Women's clothing | -0.17633 | 0.025524 | 13.84376 | 0.742386 |
Children's clothing | -0.00054 | 0.000862 | 0.267848 | 0.027241 |
Other Clothing | 0.029442 | -0.00308 | -3.3534 | 0.867552 |
Clothing supplies & services | -0.00295 | 0.000601 | 0.434927 | 0.015415 |
Men's footwear | -0.02062 | 0.003132 | 1.23944 | 0.597497 |
Women's footwear | -0.06346 | 0.008629 | 5.976196 | 0.878226 |
Children's footwear | 0.002005 | -8.35E-05 | -0.35364 | 0.250285 |
Other Footwear | 0.010164 | -1.05E-03 | -1.32814 | 0.780407 |
Footwear supplies & services | 0.003267 | -3.81E-04 | -0.3558 | 0.337931 |
Public transport within NZ | -0.06172 | 0.009624 | 5.100902 | 0.503206 |
a | b | c | R-squared | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Overseas travel | -0.47099 | 0.07091 | 28.55522 | 0.787953 |
Road vehicles | 0.291782 | -0.02883 | -31.0849 | 0.652508 |
Vehicle ownership expenses | 0.625611 | -0.0743 | -42.9299 | 0.569541 |
Private transport costs n.e.c | -0.01354 | 0.002442 | 1.589636 | 0.058705 |
Tobacco products | 0.166991 | -0.0214 | -8.79842 | 0.620878 |
Alcohol | -0.12924 | 0.021882 | 7.49086 | 0.629366 |
Medical goods | -0.02832 | 0.004974 | 3.036628 | 0.105698 |
Toiletries and cosmetics | 0.00956 | 0.000191 | -0.92042 | 0.395319 |
Personal goods | 0.032463 | -0.00257 | -3.42718 | 0.58933 |
Pets, racehorses and livestock | 0.120291 | -0.01498 | -7.75913 | 0.470165 |
Stationery and office equip | 0.070482 | -0.00593 | -5.10796 | 0.308231 |
Leisure goods | 0.019047 | 0.000662 | -4.02311 | 0.757771 |
Recreational vehicles | 0.011469 | -0.00076 | -2.11383 | 0.635397 |
Goods n.e.c. | -0.0119 | 0.002321 | 0.9711 | 0.140835 |
Health services | -0.12371 | 0.020146 | 11.10986 | 0.545345 |
Personal services | -0.10878 | 0.015507 | 9.209476 | 0.352852 |
Educational and tuition | 0.026106 | -0.00101 | 1.068944 | 0.17518 |
Accommodation services | -0.07752 | 0.011855 | 4.266511 | 0.679455 |
Fin, insurance and legal | 0.097855 | -0.00857 | -2.83561 | 0.185043 |
Vocational services | -0.00239 | 0.000818 | -0.75566 | 0.896757 |
Leisure services | -0.03519 | 0.009307 | 0.15564 | 0.86498 |
Services n.e.c. | 0.061889 | -0.00639 | -7.72831 | 0.46135 |
Outgoings n.e.c. | 0.207629 | -0.02421 | -17.3681 | 0.078868 |
Notes
- [15]Several commodity groups were excluded on the grounds that they more closely represented savings rather than expenditure. The ratio of averages is of course not the same as the average budget share (though earlier experiments using data for individual households showed that the differences were minor).
- [16]However, it does not guarantee that the predicted weights always lie in the range , though in practice this was not a serious problem; a few negative values at low total expenditure levels for some goods were set to zero and the other shares were adjusted accordingly to maintain the adding-up requirement.
Range (OOOs) | no. | Average Income | Range (OOOs) | no. | Average Income | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
- 1 | 93,213 | 409.83 | 30 | -31 | 41,890 | 30,414 | .00 | ||
1 | -2 | 61,912 | 1,452.57 | 31 | -32 | 34,770 | 31,507 | .18 | |
2 | -3 | 41,329 | 2,521.56 | 32 | -33 | 44,251 | 32,477 | .18 | |
3 | -4 | 44,486 | 3,544.49 | 33 | -34 | 38,084 | 33,533 | .93 | |
4 | -5 | 36,385 | 4,552.98 | 34 | -35 | 33,849 | 34,534 | .91 | |
5 | -6 | 43,644 | 5,437.80 | 35 | -36 | 30,837 | 35,526 | .43 | |
6 | -7 | 32,442 | 6,580.17 | 36 | -37 | 27,936 | 36,512 | .18 | |
7 | -8 | 55,677 | 7,495.72 | 37 | -38 | 34,878 | 37,548 | .02 | |
8 | -9 | 67,115 | 8,371.65 | 38 | -39 | 31,082 | 38,498 | .93 | |
9 | - | 9.5 | 66,408 | 9,267.31 | 39 | -40 | 25,273 | 39,483 | .37 |
9.5 | - | 10 | 42,052 | 9,707.22 | 40 | -41 | 27,987 | 40,563 | .92 |
10 | - | 11 | 143,426 | 10,669.95 | 41 | -42 | 30,355 | 41,480 | .31 |
11 | - | 12 | 89,621 | 11,513.70 | 42 | -43 | 17,037 | 42,551 | .03 |
12 | - | 13 | 74,977 | 12,571.58 | 43 | -44 | 19,855 | 43,478 | .16 |
13 | - | 14 | 80,137 | 13,429.31 | 44 | -45 | 20,373 | 44,647 | .87 |
14 | - | 15 | 163,260 | 14,396.08 | 45 | -46 | 15,506 | 45,453 | .50 |
15 | - | 16 | 53,649 | 15,422.00 | 46 | -47 | 15,027 | 46,560 | .53 |
16 | - | 17 | 52,664 | 16,568.82 | 47 | -48 | 15,720 | 47,510 | .66 |
17 | - | 18 | 38,984 | 17,472.11 | 48 | -49 | 17,132 | 48,471 | .26 |
18 | - | 19 | 48,558 | 18,469.33 | 49 | -50 | 12,519 | 49,700 | .59 |
19 | - | 20 | 46,773 | 19,566.15 | 50 | -52 | 28,862 | 51,011 | .51 |
20 | - | 21 | 47,134 | 20,556.02 | 52 | -54 | 26,642 | 52,891 | .96 |
21 | - | 22 | 37,598 | 21,524.06 | 54 | -56 | 19,947 | 54,980 | .98 |
22 | - | 23 | 37,181 | 22,572.31 | 56 | -58 | 24,379 | 56,876 | .89 |
23 | - | 24 | 35,388 | 23,539.56 | 58 | -60 | 19,203 | 59,208 | .08 |
24 | - | 25 | 32,699 | 24,518.45 | 60 | -65 | 52,194 | 62,407 | .42 |
25 | - | 26 | 31,564 | 25,449.60 | 65 | -70 | 24,748 | 67,319 | .34 |
26 | - | 27 | 30,796 | 26,333.18 | 70 | -80 | 43,913 | 74,481 | .48 |
27 | - | 28 | 37,842 | 27,465.45 | 80 | -90 | 22,783 | 85,128 | .34 |
28 | - | 29 | 35,810 | 28,586.43 | 90 | 100 | 19,963 | 94,708 | .39 |
29 | - | 30 | 35,872 | 29,622.28 | Over | 100 | 47,218 | 182,074 | .25 |
Income distribution
The grouped frequency distribution of taxable income in New Zealand for 2000-2001 is given in Appendix Table 3. This distribution is for income from all sources, and covers employed and self employed individuals. A histogram of this distribution is shown in Appendix Figure 1. The second mode at the bottom of the distribution raises a problem when using the standard two-parameter lognormal distribution. The pragmatic solution was adopted of adjusting the frequencies at the bottom of the distribution, as shown by smaller marked blocks for the two lowest income classes. It has in fact been found that New Zealand bimodal distributions can be modelled using a mixture distribution comprising a weighted average of lognormal and exponential distributions; see Bakker and Creedy (1999)
The resulting values were then used to obtain the mean and variance of logarithms reported above. The implied arithmetic mean value (using the properties of the lognormal mentioned above) was found to be close to the arithmetic mean calculated directly from the distribution.
Tax rates
Ad valorem tax-exclusive indirect tax rates are required for the same commodity groups as listed in Appendix Tables 1 and 2. In most cases the appropriate rate is simply the GST rate of 0.125. For rent and overseas travel, the rate is zero. In other cases, particularly where excises are involved, the computation of an effective ad valorem rate is complicated by the use of unit taxes, in combination with GST, and by the need to consolidate a wide variety of goods into a single category. The non-zero rates differing from the standard GST rate are as follows: road vehicles 0.07054; vehicle ownership expenses 0.58642; tobacco products 2.39845; alcohol 0.46819; recreational vehicles 0.0625; financial, insurance and legal services 0.0625; and expenditure not elsewhere included 0.23. For details on the computation of these rates, see Young (2002).
References#
Bakker, A. and Creedy, J. (1999) Macroeconomic variables and income inequality in New Zealand: an exploration using conditional mixture distributions. New Zealand Economic Papers 33: 59-79.
Creedy, J. (1985) Dynamics of Income Distribution. (Oxford: Basil Blackwell.)
Creedy, J. and Gemmell, N. (2002) The built-in flexibility of income and consumption taxes: a survey. Journal of Economic Surveys 44:509-532.
Creedy, J. and Gemmell, N. (2003) The revenue responsiveness of income and consumption taxes in the UK. The Manchester School (forthcoming).
Creedy, J. and Gemmell, N. (2003a) The revenue elasticity of taxes in the UK. mimeo.
Giorno, C., Richardson, P., Roseveare, D. and Van den Noord, P. (1995) Estimating potential output, output gaps and structural budget balances. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No 152.
Johnson, P. and Lambert, P. (1989) Measuring the revenue responsiveness of income tax revenue to income growth: a review and some UK values. Fiscal Studies 10:1-18.
Musgrave, R. A. and Thin, T. (1948) Income tax progression. Journal of Political Economy 56: 498-514.
van den Noord, P. (2000) The size and role of automatic fiscal stabilizers in the 1990s and beyond. OECD Economics Department Working Paper, No. 230.
Young, L. (2002) Ad valorem indirect tax rates in New Zealand. New Zealand Treasury Internal Paper (#435217).